SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 533
Download to read offline
International Trade Theory and
                              Policy Analysis
                                       by Steven Suranovic

                               The George Washington University




                         ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED

The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. The content is owned
by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of the work, a printed copy of the work and you
MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright
message attached. You MAY NOT reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use
any portion of this Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the
Study Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the webmaster@internationalecon.
com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality,
reliability or usefulness of the Content at the Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis.
International Trade Theory & Policy
by Steven M. Suranovic

Chapter 5
Introductory Issues
©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms




Table of Contents                                   Problem Sets

             The International Economy                          LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional
5-1
                                                                LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate
5-2          What is International                              LEVEL 3: Advanced Intermediate
             Economics?
5-3          Brief Outline
                                                    LEVEL 1
5-4          Some Trade Terminology
5-5          Valuable Lessons of                                Jeopardy 5-1
             International Trade Theory
 5-5A        Lesson A
 5-5B        Lesson B                               Answer Keys
 5-5C        Lesson C
                                                           r    Internet Explorer Download
 5-5D        Lesson D
                                                                Center
 5-5E        Lesson E
 5-5F        Lesson F                               Answer keys to the problem sets are for sale
                                                    in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for easier
                                                    viewing and printing. Purchases must be
DOWNLOAD Chapter 5 in PDF format.
                                                    made using a recent Internet Explorer
                                                    browser. Revenues from these sales will
                                                    help us to expand and improve the content
                                                    at this site.



Related Links
      r   Deardorff's Glossary of International
                                                       r       Think Again: International Trade
          Economics
                                                               Article by Arvind Panagariya that
          Alan Deardorff's (UMichigan)
                                                               highlights some important
          collection of citations and definitions
                                                               regularities about international trade.
          regarding international economics.



Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual
property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy
of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work
provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT
reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this
Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study
Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the
webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the
accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the
Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis.

HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE
Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Introductory Issues," The
International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch5/
ch5.html.
The International Economy

            by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2007


Trade 5-1
            International economics is growing in importance as a field of study
            because of the rapid integration of international economic markets. More
            and more, businesses, consumers and governments realize that their lives
            are increasingly affected, not just by what goes on in their own town, state
            or country, but by what is happening around the world. Consumers can buy
            goods and services from all over the world in their local shops. Local
            businesses must compete with these foreign products. However, these same
            businesses also have new opportunities to expand their markets by selling
            in a multitude of other countries. The advance of telecommunications is
            rapidly reducing the cost of providing services internationally and the
            internet will assuredly change the nature of many products and services as
            it expands markets even further than today.

            Markets have been going global, and everyone knows it.

            One simple way to see this is to look at the growth of exports in the world
            during the past 50+ years. The following figure shows overall annual
            exports measured in billions of US dollars from 1948 to 2005. Recognizing
            that one country's exports are another country's imports, one can see the
            exponential growth in trade during the past 50 years.
However, rapid growth in the value of exports does not necessarily indicate
that trade is becoming more important. Instead, one needs to look at the
share of traded goods in relation to the size of the world economy. The
adjoining figure shows world exports as a percentage of world GDP for the
years 1970 to 2005. It shows a steady increase in trade as a share of the size
of the world economy. World exports grew from just over 10% of GDP in
1970 to almost 30% by 2005. Thus, trade is not only rising rapidly in
absolute terms, it is becoming relatively more important too.




One other indicator of world interconnectedness can be seen in changes in
the amount of foreign direct investment (FDI). FDI is foreign ownership of
productive activities and thus is another way in which foreign economic
influence can affect a country. The adjoining figure shows the stock, or the
sum total value, of FDI around the world taken as a percentage of world
GDP between 1980 and 2004. It gives an indication of the importance of
foreign ownership and influence around the world. As can be seen, the
share of FDI has grown dramatically from around 5% of world GDP in
1980 to over 20% of GDP just 25 years later.
The growth of international trade and investment has been stimulated
partly by the steady decline of trade barriers since the Great Depression of
the 1930s. In the post World War II era the General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade, or GATT, was an agreement that prompted regular negotiations
among a growing body of members to reduce tariffs (import taxes) on
imported goods on a reciprocal basis. During each of these regular
negotiations, (eight of these rounds were completed between 1948 and
1994), countries promised to reduce their tariffs on imports in exchange for
concessions, or tariffs reductions, by other GATT members. When the
most recent completed round was finished in 1994, the member countries
succeeded in extending the agreement to include liberalization promises in
a much larger sphere of influence. Now countries would not only lower
tariffs on goods trade, but would begin to liberalize agriculture and services
market. They would eliminate the many quota systems - like the multi-fiber
agreement in clothing - that had sprouted up in previous decades. And they
would agree to adhere to certain minimum standards to protect intellectual
property rights such as patents, trademarks and copyrights. The WTO was
created to manage this system of new agreements, to provide a forum for
regular discussion of trade matters and to implement a well-defined process
for settling trade disputes that might arise among countries.

As of 2006, 149 countries were members of the WTO "trade liberalization
club" and many more countries were still negotiating entry. As the club
grows to include more members, and if the latest round of trade
liberalization discussion called the Doha round concludes with an
agreement, world markets will become increasingly open to trade and
investment. [Note: the Doha round of discussions was begun in 2001 and
remains uncompleted as of 2006]

Another international push for trade liberalization has come in the form of
regional free trade agreements. Over 200 regional trade agreements around
the world have been notified, or announced, to the WTO. Many countries
have negotiated these with neighboring countries or major trading partners,
to promote even faster trade liberalization. In part these have arisen
because of the slow, plodding pace of liberalization under the
GATT/WTO. In part it has occurred because countries have wished to
promote interdependence and connectedness with important economic or
strategic trade partners. In any case, the phenomenon serves to open
international markets even further than achieved in the WTO.

These changes in economic patterns and the trend towards ever increasing
openness are an important aspect of the more exhaustive phenomenon
known as globalization. Globalization more formally refers to the
economic, social, cultural or environmental changes that tend to
interconnect peoples around the world. Since the economic aspects of
globalization are certainly one of the most pervasive of these changes, it is
increasingly important to understand the implications of a global
marketplace on consumers, businesses and governments. That is where the
study of international economics begins.



International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2007 Steven M. Suranovic .
Last Updated on 12/24/06
What is International Economics?

            by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-2
            International economics is a field of study which assesses the implications of
            international trade in goods and services and international investment.

            There are two broad sub-fields within international economics: international trade and
            international finance.

            International trade is a field in economics that applies microeconomic models to help
            understand the international economy. Its content includes the same tools that are
            introduced in microeconomics courses, including supply and demand analysis, firm and
            consumer behavior, perfectly competitive, oligopolistic and monopolistic market
            structures, and the effects of market distortions. The typical course describes economic
            relationships between consumers, firms, factor owners, and the government.

            The objective of an international trade course is to understand the effects on individuals
            and businesses because of international trade itself, because of changes in trade policies
            and due to changes in other economic conditions. The course will develop arguments
            that support a free trade policy as well as arguments that support various types of
            protectionist policies. By the end of the course, students should better understand the
            centuries-old controversy between free trade and protectionism.

            International finance applies macroeconomic models to help understand the
            international economy. Its focus is on the interrelationships between aggregate economic
            variables such as GDP, unemployment rates, inflation rates, trade balances, exchange
            rates, interest rates, etc. This field expands macroeconomics to include international
            exchanges. Its focus is on the significance of trade imbalances, the determinants of
            exchange rates and the aggregate effects of government monetary and fiscal policies.
            Among the most important issues addressed are the pros and cons of fixed versus
            floating exchange rate systems. [Note: A separate collection of web materials on
            international finance is available at The International Finance Webtext].


            International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated
            on 7/17/04
Brief Outline

            by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-3
            The course is divided into four distinct sections.
            1. International Trade History and Current Issues

                 q   The Terminology of International Trade

                 q   Trade Policy Instruments

                 q   Trade History

                 q   Current Trade Issues

            2. The Effects of International Trade

            In this section a variety of models are developed which highlight the following five basic
            reasons that trade occurs.

                 q   differences in technology

                 q   differences in resource endowments

                 q   differences in consumer demand

                 q   existence of economics of scale in production

                 q   existence of government policies

            The models address the effects that trade has on the prices of goods and services, the
            profits of firms, the well-being of consumers, the wages of workers, and the return to
            other factors of production.

            3. The Effects of Trade Policies

            These models address the effects that trade policies have on the prices of goods and
            services, the profits of firms, the well-being of consumers, the wages of workers, the
            return to other factors of production and the implications for the government budget.
            This section is divided according to the following assumptions on market structure.

                1. Perfect Competition
                2. Market Imperfections and Distortions
4. Evaluating the Controversy: Free Trade or Protectionism?

This final section reviews the results of the course by applying them to the premier
controversy in international trade: whether to follow a policy of free trade or selected
protectionism. Using trade theory results, we develop the arguments that support a policy
of free trade and the arguments that support a policy of selected protectionism. We also
provide the counter-arguments or caveats that can be used against each of the arguments
supporting a particular position. In the end, the section does not reach a definitive
conclusion. It is left to the reader to decide which arguments carry the greatest validity.
However, the argument does "tilt" in the direction of free trade.


International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
on 7/17/04
Some Trade Terminology

            by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-4
            In trade policy discussions terms such as protectionism, free trade, and trade
            liberalization are used repeatedly. It is worthwhile to define these terms at the beginning.
            One other term is commonly used in the analysis of trade models, namely national
            autarky, or just autarky.

            Two extreme states or conditions could potentially be created by national government
            policies. At one extreme, a government could pursue a "laissez faire" policy with respect
            to trade and thus impose no regulation whatsoever that would impede (or encourage) the
            free voluntary exchange of goods between nations. We define this condition as free
            trade. At the other extreme, a government could impose such restrictive regulations on
            trade as to eliminate all incentive for international trade. We define this condition in
            which no international trade occurs as national autarky. Autarky represents a state of
            isolationism. (See Figure).




            Probably, a pure state of free trade or autarky has never existed in the real world. All
            nations impose some form of trade policies. And probably no government has ever had
            such complete control over economic activity as to eliminate cross-border trade entirely.
            The real world, instead, consists of countries that fall somewhere between these two
            extremes. Some countries, such as Singapore and (formerly) Hong Kong, are considered
            to be highly free trade oriented. Others, like North Korea and Cuba, have long been
            relatively closed economies and thus are closer to the state of autarky. The rest of the
            world lies somewhere in between.

            Most policy discussions are not about whether governments should pursue one of these
            two extremes. Instead, discussions focus on which direction a country should move
            along the trade spectrum. Since every country today is somewhere in the middle,
            discussions focus on whether policies should move the nation in the direction of free
            trade or in the direction of autarky.

            A movement in the direction of autarky occurs whenever a new trade policy is
            implemented if it further restricts the free flow of goods and services between countries.
            Since new trade policies invariably benefit domestic industries by reducing international
            competition, it is also referred to as protectionism.
A movement in the direction of free trade occurs when regulations on trade are removed.
Since the elimination of trade policies will generally increase the amount of international
trade, it is referred to as trade liberalization.

Trade policy discussions typically focus, then, on whether the country should increase
protectionism or whether it should pursue trade liberalization.

Note that, according to this definition of protectionism, even policies that encourage
trade, such as export subsidies, are considered protectionist since they alter the pattern
of trade that would have prevailed in the absence of government intervention. This
implies that protectionism is much more complex than can be represented along a single
dimension (as suggested in the above diagram) since protection can both increase and
decrease trade flows. Nevertheless, the representation of the trade spectrum is useful in a
number of ways.


International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
on 6/12/06
Valuable Lessons of International Trade Theory

            by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5
            In this section some of the most important lessons in international trade theory are
            briefly presented. Often, the lessons that are most interesting and valuable are those that
            teach something either counterintuitive, or at least contrary to popular opinions. A
            number of these are represented below. Each explanation also provides links to the pages
            where the arguments are more fully explained. (Note: For most students, following the
            links initially may be more confusing than helpful. However, once reading through many
            of the chapters, review of these lessons may help reinforce them).

               A. The main support for free trade arises because free trade can raise aggregate
                  economic efficiency.

                B. Trade theory shows that some people will suffer losses in free trade.

                C. A country may benefit from free trade even if it is less efficient than all other
                   countries in every industry.

               D. A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is the
                  lowest-cost producer in the world.

                E. Protection may be beneficial for a country.

                F. Although protection can be beneficial, the case for free trade remains strong.


            International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
            on 6/13/06
Lesson 5A

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5A
             The main support for free trade arises because free trade can raise
             aggregate economic efficiency.

             In most models of trade there is an improvement in aggregate efficiency when an
             economy moves from autarky to free trade. This is the same as an increase in national
             welfare. Efficiency improvements can be decomposed into two separate effects:
             production efficiency and consumption efficiency. An improvement in production
             efficiency means that countries can produce more goods and services with the same
             amount of resources. In other words, productivity rises for the given resource
             endowments available for use in production. Consumption efficiency improvements
             mean, in essence, that consumers will have a more satisfying collection of goods and
             services from which to choose.

             Many economists define the objective of the economics discipline as seeking to identify
             the best way to use scarce resources to satisfy the needs and wants of the people of a
             country. Economic efficiency is the term economists use to formally measure this
             objective. Since free trade tends to promote economic efficiency is so many models, this
             is one of the strongest arguments in support of free trade.

             This result is formally demonstrated in the Ricardian model (see page 40-9b), the
             Immobile Factor model (see page 70-15), the Specific Factor model, the Heckscher-
             Ohlin model (see page 60-10), the Demand Difference model, the simple Economies of
             Scale model, (see page 80-3) and the Monopolistic Competition model (see page 80-5e).
             It can also be demonstrated when a small country reduces barriers to trade (Consider the
             analysis on page 90-11 in reverse). Each of these models shows that a country can have a
             larger national output (i.e. GDP) and superior choices available in consumption as a
             result of free trade.


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Lesson 5B

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5B
             Trade theory shows that some people will suffer losses in free trade.
             A common misperception about international economics is that it teaches that everyone
             will benefit from free trade. One often hears that voluntary exchange, whether between
             individuals or between nations, must benefit both parties to the transaction, otherwise the
             transaction would not occur. Although this argument is valid for exchange between two
             people, the conclusion changes when one considers two countries made up of multiple
             individuals. (See pages 30-3 through 30-5)

             Economists themselves often espouse the position that free trade is beneficial to all,
             albeit often with the caveat, "... at least in the long run". In the short run, factors of
             production may be relatively immobile across industries (see pages 70-1 and 70-2). In
             the presence of immobility, it can be shown that while export industries would gain from
             free trade, import-competing industries would lose (see page 70-17). Thus, in the short
             run, resource adjustment problems can explain losses to some groups.

             In the long run, once all resources can move to alternative industries, some models (e.g.
             Ricardian) suggest that everyone in the economy would benefit from free trade (See page
             40-9a). Other models (e.g. Heckscher-Ohlin) however, suggest that some groups may
             continue to lose even in the long run (See page 60-12).

             Another complication is that not everyone will make it to the long run. As John Maynard
             Keynes once remarked, "In the long run, we are all dead." If not dead, it is surely true
             that some individuals will retire from the labor force before the long run arrives. These
             individuals may be unfortunate enough to experience only the negative short-run losses
             to an industry. Upon retirement, their short-term losses may carry over to long-run losses.

             Economists will often dismiss concerns about potential losses from trade liberalization
             by proposing that compensation be provided. The "compensation principle" suggests that
             some of the gains could be taken away from the winners and given to the losers such that
             everyone becomes better-off as a result of free trade. Although the principle is valid
             conceptually, effective implementation of it seems unlikely (See discussion on
             page 60-13).


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Lesson 5C

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5C
             A country may benefit from free trade even if it is less efficient than all
             other countries in every industry.

             It makes sense that one firm would be more successful than another firm in a local
             market if it could produce its output more efficiently - that is at lower cost - than the
             second firm. If the two firms produce identical products, then the less efficient firm is
             likely to be driven out of business, generating losses. If we extend this example to an
             international market then it would also make sense that a more efficient foreign firm
             would absorb business from a less efficient domestic firm. Finally, suppose all firms in
             all industries domestically were less efficient than all firms in all industries in the foreign
             countries. It would then seem logically impossible for any domestic firms to succeed in
             competition in the international market with the foreign firms. International competition
             would seemingly have only negative effects upon the less efficient domestic firms and
             the domestic country.

             This seemingly logical conclusion is refuted by the Ricardian model of comparative
             advantage. Ricardo demonstrated the surprising result that less efficient firms in a
             country can indeed compete with foreign firms in international markets. In addition, by
             moving to free trade, the less efficient country can generate welfare improvements for
             everybody in the country. Free trade can even benefit a country that is less efficient at
             producing everything (See page 40-9).

             What's more, in a free market system, differences in prices and profit-seeking behavior
             are all that is needed to induce countries to produce and export the "right" goods and
             trade to their national benefit. (see especially 40-8)


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Lesson 5D

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5D
             A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is
             the lowest-cost producer in the world.

             This result is a corollary of Lesson 3. As argued there, it seems reasonable to think that a
             more efficient firm (i.e., one who produces at lower cost) would drive its less efficient
             competitors out of business. The same would seem to follow if the two firms are
             domestic and foreign and the two firms compete in international markets.

             However, the Ricardian model of comparative advantage argues that a firm in one
             country, even if it is the lowest-cost producer in the world, may be forced out of business
             once the country liberalizes trade with the rest of the world. Even more surprising,
             despite the decline of this industry, the move to free trade can generate welfare
             improvements for everybody in the country. In other words, losing production in a
             highly efficient industry can be consistent with an improvement in welfare for
             everyone. This contradicts the logic above which would suggest that more efficient
             (lower-cost) firms should always win (See page 40-9).

             It is important to note that this result does not imply that every decline of an efficient
             industry will improve welfare. Instead, the model merely suggests that one should not
             jump to the conclusion that the loss of an efficient industry will have negative effects for
             the country as a whole.


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Lesson 5E

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5E
             Protection may be beneficial for a country.
             Sometimes the support for free trade by economists seems so strong that one might think
             there is very little evidence to suggest that protection could be beneficial. In actuality,
             there are numerous examples in the trade literature which show that protection can be
             beneficial for a country. The examples fall into two categories.

             The first category contains trade policies which raise domestic national welfare, but
             which reduce aggregate world welfare at the same time. These type of policies are
             sometimes called "beggar-thy-neighbor" policies since benefits to one country can only
             arise by forcing losses upon its trading partners. The most notable example is the terms
             of trade argument for protection which is valid whenever a country is either a large
             importer or a large exporter of a product in international markets (See page 90-9). A
             second type of beggar-thy-neighbor policy is strategic trade policy. These policies
             benefit the domestic country by shifting profit away from either foreign firms or foreign
             consumers (See pages 100-5).

             The second category of beneficial trade policies are those which not only raise domestic
             welfare but raise world welfare as well. Some trade policies may act to correct prevailing
             market imperfections or distortions. If the welfare improvement caused by correcting the
             imperfection or distortion exceeds any additional distortion caused by the trade policy,
             then world welfare may rise. Many well-known justifications for protection, including
             the potential for unemployment (see page 100-3), infant industries (see page 100-4), the
             presence of foreign monopolies, (see page 100-5) and concern for national security (see
             page 100-7), arise because of the assumption of market imperfections or distortions.


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Lesson 5F

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 5-5F
             Although protection can be beneficial, the case for free trade remains
             strong.

             The argument in support of free trade is often different depending on whether the
             speaker is in a political setting or an academic setting. In a political setting, political
             realities will often force the speaker to emphasize all of the positive aspects of free trade
             and to hardly even mention any negative aspects. The reason for this is that talking
             of the negative effects of free trade will offer up ammunition to one's opponents who
             may then use these statements against him in future debates.

             Since most people will have learned the argument for free trade by listening to political
             and public policy debates in the news media, they are likely to believe that economics
             teaches that free trade is good for all people, in all countries, at all times. This belief may
             lead people, especially those obviously hurt by freer trade policies, to doubt whether
             economics has anything useful to say about the real world.

             However, the academic argument for free trade, is much more sophisticated than the
             typical political argument. As readers of this site will learn, free trade will cause harm to
             some (see 5-5b), as well as good to others. Furthermore, certain selected protectionist
             policies can be good for individuals, and for the nation (see 5-5e), but they will also
             cause harm as well.

             Thus, the choice between free trade and selected protection is not as simple as typically
             presented by political advocates on one side or the other. In essence, one must choose
             between the good and bad that comes with free trade, and the good and bad that comes
             with selected protectionism. In weighing the alternatives, economists often conclude that
             free trade is the more pragmatic choice, dominating, for a variety of reasons, selected
             protectionist policies.

             This more sophisticated argument for free trade is the topic of Chapter 120. The chapter
             highlights both the positive and negative aspects of free trade policies and refers readers
             back via hyperlinks to many sections in the main text to support each argument. Chapter
             120 is useful to read at the beginning of your studies to see where the course is going. It
             is even more important to read at the end, to see how everything covered in the text fits
             into the argument supporting free trade. During this second reading, the hyperlinks will
             become especially useful.


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated
             on 6/13/06
Trade Questions Jeopardy 5-1


DIRECTIONS: As in the popular TV game show, you are given an answer to a question and you
must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is "a tax on imports," then the
correct question is "What is a tariff?"


   1. Of micro- or macro-economics, the one whose methods are mostly applied in an
      international trade theory course.
   2. Of micro- or macro-economics, the one whose methods are mostly applied in an
      international finance theory course.
   3. Term of French origin used to describe a total absence of government regulation.
   4. Term used to describe a situation in which a country does not trade with any other
      country.
   5. The two types of economic efficiency.
   6. Term given to the principle of redistribution between winners and losers.
   7. Name of the economist who once remarked, "In the long run, we are all dead!"
   8. Term used to describe policies which raise domestic welfare while reducing
      welfare in the rest of the world.
   9. Name given to a policy that shifts profits away from foreign firms towards the
      domestic economy.
  10. The premier controversy in international trade policy analysis.




©2000-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
Last Updated on 6/13/06
International Trade Theory & Policy
by Steven M. Suranovic

Chapter 10
Trade Policy Tools
©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms




Table of Contents                           Problem Sets

          Chapter Overview                            LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional
10-0
                                                      LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate
10-1      Import Tariffs                              LEVEL 3: Advanced Intermediate

 10-1a    US Tariffs - 2004
10-2      Import Quotas
                                            LEVEL 1
10-3      Voluntary Export
          Restraints (VERs)                           Jeopardy 10-1
 10-3a    US-Japan Automobile
          VERs
 10-3b    Textile VERs                      Answer Keys
10-4      Export Taxes
                                                  r   Internet Explorer Download
10-5      Export Subsidies
                                                      Center
10-6      Voluntary Import
          Expansions (VIEs)                 Answer keys to the problem sets are for sale
10-7      Other Trade Policy Tools          in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for easier
                                            viewing and printing. Purchases must be
                                            made using a recent Internet Explorer
DOWNLOAD Chapter 10 in PDF format.          browser. Revenues from these sales will
                                            help us to expand and improve the content
                                            at this site.
Related Links

                                                     r   All About Textiles and Clothing and
                                                         the WTO
                                                         This page at the WTO website
     r   Tariff Rate Quota Administration                provides a gateway to all sorts of
         A briefing paper by the Economic                information about textile and
         Research Service at the US Dept. of             clothing agreements.
         Agriculture
     r   Agricultural Export Subsidies               r   South African Customs Tariffs
         Overview                                           Updated Weekly
         Another briefing paper by the               r   Newly Independent States: Tariff
         Economic Research Service at the                Schedules
         US Dept. of Agriculture                         This page provides links to tariffs
     r   Tariffication and Tariff Reduction              schedules for many of the Newly
         Another briefing paper by the                   Independent States.
         Economic Research Service at the            r   APEC Country: Tariff Schedules
         US Dept. of Agriculture                         This page provides links to tariffs
                                                         schedules for many of the APEC
                                                         countries. (You may need to register.
                                                         It is free).



Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual
property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy
of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work
provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT
reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this
Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study
Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the
webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the
accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the
Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis.

HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE
Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Introductory Issues," The
International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch10/
ch10.html.
Trade Policy Tools

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-0
             Trade policies come in many varieties. Generally they consist of either taxes or
             subsidies, quantitative restrictions or encouragements, on either imported or exported
             goods, services and assets. In this section we describe many of the policies that countries
             have implemented or have proposed implementing. For each policy we present examples
             of their use in the US or in other countries. The purpose of this section is not to explain
             the likely effects of each policy, but rather to define and describe the use of each policy.

                  q   Import Tariffs
                  q   Import Quotas
                  q   Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs)
                  q   Export Taxes
                  q   Export Subsidies
                  q   Voluntary Import Expansions (VIEs)
                  q   Other Trade Policies




             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
Import Tariffs

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-1
             An import tariff is a tax collected on imported goods. Generally speaking, a tariff is any
             tax or fee collected by a government. Sometimes tariff is used in a non-trade context, as
             in railroad tariffs. However, the term is much more commonly applied to a tax on
             imported goods.

             There are two basic ways in which tariffs may be levied: specific tariffs and ad valorem
             tariffs.

             A specific tariff is levied as a fixed charge per unit of imports. For example, the US
             government levies a 5.1 cent specific tariff on every wristwatch imported into the US.
             Thus, if 1000 watches are imported, the US government collects $51 in tariff revenue. In
             this case, $51 is collected whether the watch is a $40 Swatch or a $5000 Rolex.

             An ad valorem tariff is levied as a fixed percentage of the value of the commodity
             imported. "Ad valorem" is Latin for "on value" or "in proportion to the value." The US
             currently levies a 2.5% ad valorem tariff on imported automobiles. Thus if $100,000
             worth of autos are imported, the US government collects $2,500 in tariff revenue. In this
             case, $2500 is collected whether two $50,000 BMWs are imported or ten $10,000
             Hyundais.

             Occasionally both a specific and an ad valorem tariff are levied on the same product
             simultaneously. This is known as a two-part tariff. For example, wristwatches imported
             into the US face the 5.1 cent specific tariff as well as a 6.25% ad valorem tariff on the
             case and the strap and a 5.3% ad valorem tariff on the battery. Perhaps this should be
             called a three-part tariff!

             As the above examples suggest, different tariffs are generally applied to different
             commodities. Governments rarely apply the same tariff to all goods and services
             imported into the country. One exception to this occurred in 1971 when President Nixon,
             in a last-ditch effort to save the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, imposed
             a 10% ad valorem tariff on all imported goods from IMF member countries. But
             incidents such as this are uncommon.

             Thus, instead of one tariff rate, countries have a tariff schedule which specifies the tariff
             collected on every particular good and service. The schedule of tariffs charged in all
             import commodity categories is called the Harmonized Tariff Schedule of the United
             States (HTS). The commodity classifications are based on the international Harmonized
             Commodity Coding and Classification System (or the Harmonized System) established
             by the World Customs Organization.


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 6/13/06
Selected US Tariffs - 2004

              by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-1a
              The table below contains a selection of the US tariff rates specified in the 2004 US
              Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS). The complete US HTS is available at the US
              International Trade Commision website HERE. The US Treasury department provides
              historical US tariff schedules dating back to 1997 HERE. To see a small sample of US
              tariff rates from 1996, Click HERE.

              The tariff schedule below displays three columns. The first column shows the product
              classification number. The first two numbers refer to the chapter, the most general
              product specification. For example, 08 refers to chapter 8, "Edible fruit and nuts; peel of
              citrus fruit or melons." The product classification becomes more specific for each digit to
              the right. Thus 0805 refers more specifically to "Citrus fruit, fresh or dried." 0805 40
              refers to "Grapefruit," and 0805 40 40 refers to "Grapefruit entering between August 1
              and September 30." This classification system is harmonized among about 200 countries
              up to the first 6 digits and is overseen by the World Customs Organization.

              The second column gives a brief description of the product. The third column displays
              the "General Rate of Duty" for that particular product. This is the tariff that the US
              applies to all countries with Most Favored Nation (MFN) status, or as it is now referred to
              in the US, "Normal Trade Relations" (NTR). The status was renamed NTR to provide a
              more accurate description of the term. One provision in our GATT/WTO agreements is
              that the US promises to provide every WTO member country with MFN status. As a
              matter of policy, the US also typically grants most non-WTO countries with the same
              status. For example, Russia is currently (Sept 2004) not a member of the WTO, but the
              US applies our NTR tariffs rates on imports from them.

              The final column lists special rates of duty that apply to select countries under special
              circumstances. For each product you will see a tariff rate followed by a list of symbols in
              parentheses. The symbols indicate the trade act or free trade agreement that provides
              special tariff treatment to those countries. A complete list of these is shown below.
              Symbols that include a "+" or "*" generally refer to special exceptions that apply for
              some countries with that product. The non-MFN tariff rate is also listed in this column.
              The only countries now subject to the non-MFN tariffs are Cuba, Laos and North Korea.
              (Note, Cuba is a WTO member, thus the US does not always honor its WTO obligations)
              The last countries removed from the Non-MFN category were Serbia and Montenegro in
              December 2003. Ten years ago, other countries in the non-MFN category included
              Vietnam, Iran and Afghanistan. Finally, note that some countries, such as Cuba, have
              other provisions, such as trade embargoes, that further restrict access of their products.
Special Tariff Classifications in the US

 A, A*, A+       Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) (More info: page 11)

 B               Automotive Products Trade Act (More info: page 21)

 CA, MX          North American FTA (NAFTA)
                 Canada and Mexico (More info: page 31)

 D               African Growth and Opportunity Act (More info: page 170)

 E               Carribean Basin Economic Recovery Act (More info: page 23)

 IL              US-Israel FTA (More info: page 26)

 J, J*, J+       Andean Trade Preference Act (More info: page 29)

 R               US-Carribean Trade Partnership Act (More info: page 171)

 JO              US-Jordan FTA (More info: page 172)

 SG              US-Singapore FTA (More info: page 176)

 CL              US-Chile FTA (More info: page 267)


The products presented below were selected to demonstrate several noteworthy features
of US trade policy. The WTO reports in the 2004 US Trade Policy Review that most
goods enter the US either duty free or with very low tariffs. Coffee and FAX machines
are two goods, shown below, representative of the many goods that enter duty free. The
average MFN tariff in the US in 2002 was about 5% although for agricultural goods the
rate was almost twice as high. About 7% of US tariffs exceed 15%, these mostly on
sensitive products such as peanuts, dairy, footwear, textiles and clothing. The trade-
weighted average tariff in the US was only about 1.5% in 2003.

One interesting feature of the tariff schedule is the degree of specificity of the products in
the HTS schedule. Besides product type, categories are divided according to weight, size
or the time of year. Note especially the description of ceramic tableware and bicycles.

Tariffs vary according to time of entry, as with cauliflower, grapefruit and grapes. This
reflects the harvest season for those product in the US. When the tariff is low, that
product is out of season in the US. Higher tariffs are in place when US output in the
product rises.

Notice the tariffs on cauliflower and broccoli. They are lower if the vegetables are
unprocessed. If the product is cut or sliced before arriving in the US, the tariff rises to
14%. This reflects a case of tariff escalation. Tariff escalation means charging a higher
tariff the greater the degree of processing for a product. This is a common practice
among many developed countries and serves to protect domestic processing industries.
Developing countries complain that these practices impede their development by
preventing them from competing in more advanced industries. Consequently, tariff
escalation is a common topic of discussion during trade liberalization talks.
Tariffs rates also vary with different components of the same product, as with watches.
Note also that watches have both specific tariffs and ad valorem tariffs applied.

Notice that tariffs on cars in the US is 2.5%, but the tariff on truck imports is 10 times
that rate at 25%. The truck tariff dates back to 1963 and is sometimes referred to as the
"chicken tax." It was implemented, primarily to affect Volkswagon, in retaliation for
West Germany's high tariff on chicken imports from the US. Today, Canada and Mexico
are exempt from the tariff due to NAFTA and Australia will also be exempt with the new
US-Australia FTA. The truck tax is set to be a contentious issue in current US-Thailand
FTA discussions.

The tariff rates themselves are typically set to several significant digits. One has to
wonder why the US charges 4.4% on golf clubs rather than an even 4 or 5%. Much
worse is the tariff rate on cane sugar with six significant digits.

The special tariff rates are often labeled "Free," meaning thise goods enter duty-free from
that group of countries. Note that Chile and Singapore sometimes have tariff rates in
between the MFN rate and zero. This reflects the phase in process of the free trade area.
Most FTAs include a 5-15 year phase in period during which time tariffs are reduced
annually towards zero.




                Selected Tariffs in the US 2004

 HTS Code       Description                           MFN/NTR           Special Tariff
                                                       Tariff

 0704.10.20     Cauliflower, Broccoli                  2.5% (June 5-     Free (A,CA,
                                                         Oct 25)        CL,E, IL,J,JO,
                                                                           MX,SG)
 0704.10.40                                           10% (Other,
                                                     not reduced in      Free (A,CA,
                                                          size)         CL,E, IL,J,JO,
                                                                             MX)
 0704.10.60                                                               7.5% (SG)
                                                      14% (Cut or
                                                        sliced)          Free (A,CA,
                                                                        CL,E, IL,J,JO,
                                                                            MX)
                                                                         12.2% (SG)

                                                                          Non-MFN:
                                                                            50%
0805.40.40   Grapefruit                        1.9¢/kg (Aug-   Free (CA,D,E,
                                                    Sep)       IL, J,JO,MX,
                                                                    SG)
                                                                1.6¢/kg (CL)
0805.40.60                                     1.5¢/kg (Oct)
                                                               Free (CA,D,E,
                                                               IL, J,JO,MX,
                                                                    SG)
0805.40.80                                     2.5¢/kg (Nov-    1.1¢/kg (CL)
                                                    Jul)
                                                               Free (CA,D,E,
                                                               IL, J,JO,MX)
                                                                2.2¢/kg (CL,
                                                                    SG)

                                                                Non-MFN:
                                                                 3.3¢/kg


0806.10.20   Grapes, fresh                     $1.13/m3 (Feb   Free (A+,CA,
                                                15-Mar 31)     CL,D,E, IL,J,
0806.10.40                                                      JO,MX,SG)
                                                Free (Apr 1-
0806.10.60                                        Jun 30)       Non-MFN:
                                                                 $8.83/m3
                                               $1.80/m3 (any
                                                 other time)

6912.00.45   Ceramic tableware; plates not         4.5%        Free (A+,CA,
             over 22.9 cm in maximum                           CL,D,E, J,JO,
             diameter and valued over $6                         MX,SG)
             per dozen; plates over 22.9 but
             not over 27.9 cm in maximum
             diameter and valued over $8.50
             per dozen                                          Non-MFN:
                                                                  55%


7116.10.25   Cultured Pearls                       5.5%        Free (A,CA,
                                                               CL,L,J, JO,
                                                                  MX)

                                                                4.1% (SG)

                                                                Non-MFN:
                                                                  110%
8703.2x.00   Motor cars, principally                  2.5%          Free (A+,B,
             designed for the transport of                          CA,CL,D, E,
             persons, of all cylinder                               IL,J,JO,MX,
             capacities                                                  SG)

                                                                    Non-MFN:
                                                                      10%


8704.22.50   Motor vehicles for the                   25%           Free (A+,B,
             transport of goods (i.e., trucks),                     CA,CL,D, E,
             gross vehicle weight exceeding                          IL,J,MX)
             5 metric tons but less than 20
             metric tons                                             15% (JO)

                                                                    22.5% (SG)

                                                                    Non-MFN:
                                                                      25%


8712.00.15   Bicycles having both wheels              11%          Free (A+,CA,
             not exceeding 63.5 cm in                              CL,D,E, IL,J,
             diameter                                                  MX)

                                                                     2.2% (JO)

                                                                     9.6% (SG)

                                                                    Non-MFN:
                                                                      30%


1701.11.05   Cane sugar:                            1.4606¢/kg      Free (A*,CA,
                                                  less .020668¢/   CL,E*,IL, J,JO,
                                                    kg for each       MX,SG)
                                                   degree under
                                                   100 degrees       Non-MFN:
                                                    but not less     4.3817¢/kg
                                                  than .943854¢/   less .0622005¢/
                                                         kg          kg for each
                                                                    degree under
                                                                     100 degrees
                                                                     but not less
                                                                         than
                                                                    2.831562¢/kg
6404.11.20     Sports footwear; tennis shoes,          10.5%          Free (CA,CL,
                basket-ball shoes, gym shoes,                          D,IL,J+, MX,
                training shoes and the like:                                 R)
                Having uppers of which over
                50% of the external surface                              2.1% (JO)
                area is leather.
                                                                         9.1% (SG)

                                                                        Non-MFN:
                                                                          35%


 9506.31.00     Golf clubs                                4.4%          Free (A,CA,
                                                                       CL,E,IL, J,JO,
                                                                         MX,SG)

                                                                        Non-MFN:
                                                                          30%


 9101.11.40     Wristwatches                         51¢ each +        38.2¢ each +
                                                    6.25% on case      4.6% on case
                                                      and strap +       and strap +
                                                       5.3% on           3.9% on
                                                        battery         battery (CL,
                                                                            SG)

                                                                       Free (CA,D,E,
                                                                        IL,J, J+,JO,
                                                                           MX,R


 8517.21.00     Fax machines                               Free           Non-MFN:
                                                                           35%

 0901.21.00     Coffee, non-decaffeinated                Free           Non-MFN:
                                                                           Free

 0902.10.10     Tea, green tea, flavored                   6.4%          Free (A,CA,
                                                                       CL,E,IL, J,JO,
                                                                           MX)

                                                                         4.8% (SG)

                                                                        Non-MFN:
                                                                          20%



One thing to think about while reviewing this tariff schedule is the administrative cost of
monitoring and taxing imported goods. Not only does the customs service incur costs to
properly categorize and measure goods entering the country, but foreign firms
themselves must be attuned to the intricacies of the tariff schedule of all of the countries
to which it exports. All of this requires the attention and time of employees of the firms
and represents a cost of doing business. These administrative costs are rarely included in
the evaluation of trade policies.

An administratively cheaper alternative would be to charge a fixed ad valorem tariff on
all goods that enter, much like a local sales tax. However, it would be almost impossible
for political reasons to switch to this much simpler alternative.



International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Last Updated
on 6/13/06
Import Quotas

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-2
             Import quotas are limitations on the quantity of goods that can be imported into the
             country during a specified period of time. An import quota is typically set below the free
             trade level of imports. In this case it is called a binding quota. If a quota is set at or above
             the free trade level of imports then it is referred to as a non-binding quota. Goods that are
             illegal within a country effectively have a quota set equal to zero. Thus many countries
             have a zero quota on narcotics and other illicit drugs.

             There are two basic types of quotas: absolute quotas and tariff-rate quotas. Absolute
             quotas limit the quantity of imports to a specified level during a specified period of time.
             Sometimes these quotas are set globally and thus affect all imports while sometimes they
             are set only against specified countries. Absolute quotas are generally administered on a
             first-come first-served basis. For this reason, many quotas are filled shortly after the
             opening of the quota period. Tariff-rate quotas allow a specified quantity of goods to be
             imported at a reduced tariff rate during the specified quota period.

             In the US in 1996, milk, cream, brooms, ethyl alcohol, anchovies, tuna, olives and durum
             wheat were subject to tariff-rate quotas. Other quotas exist on peanuts, cotton, sugar and
             syrup.

             In the US most quotas are administered the US Customs Service. The exceptions include
             dairy products, administered by the Department of Agriculture, and watches and watch
             movements, administered by the Departments of the Interior and the Commerce
             Department.



             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 6/13/06
Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs)

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-3
             A voluntary export restraint is a restriction set by a government on the quantity of
             goods that can be exported out of a country during a specified period of time. Often the
             word voluntary is placed in quotes because these restraints are typically implemented
             upon the insistence of the importing nations.

             Typically VERs arise when the import-competing industries seek protection from a surge
             of imports from particular exporting countries. VERs are then offered by the exporter to
             appease the importing country and to avoid the effects of possible trade restraints on the
             part of the importer. Thus VERs are rarely completely voluntary.

             Also, VERs are typically implemented on a bilateral basis, that is, on exports from one
             exporter to one importing country. VERs have been used since the 1930s at least, and
             have been applied to products ranging from textiles and footwear to steel, machine tools
             and automobiles. They became a popular form of protection during the 1980s, perhaps in
             part because they did not violate countries' agreements under the GATT. As a result of
             the Uruguay round of the GATT, completed in 1994, WTO members agreed not to
             implement any new VERs and to phase out any existing VERs over a four year period.
             Exceptions can be granted for one sector in each importing country.

             Some interesting examples of VERs occured with auto exports from Japan in the early
             1980s and with textile exports in the 1950s and 60s.

                  q   US-Japan Automobile VERs
                  q   Textile VERs


             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
US-Japan Automobile VERs

              by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-3a
              In 1981, the US was suffering the effects of the second OPEC oil price shock. Faced
              with higher gasoline prices, consumers began to shift their demand from low fuel
              efficiency US autos to higher fuel efficiency Japanese autos. This increase in auto
              imports contributed to lower sales and profits of US automakers. Chrysler Corporation
              nearly went bankrupt in 1981, and probably would have, if the US government had not bailed
              it out with subsidized loans. The US auto industry filed an escape clause petition with
              the International Trade Commision, but the ITC failed to find material injury as a result
              of the Japanese imports. The US was suffering from a recession at that time which also
              contributed to the decline in demand for US autos. The Japanese, faced with continuing
              calls by the US auto industry for legislated protection and following discussions with the
              US trade representative's office, eventually announced VERs on auto exports. These
              VERs were renewed regularly and lasted until the early 1990s.

              The bilateral nature of VERs contributes to a series of subsequent effects. Since a VER
              can raise the price of the product in the importing country, there is an incentive created to
              circumvent the restriction. In the case of the Japanese auto VERs, the circumvention took
              a variety of forms. Since the quantity of auto trade between Japan and the US was
              limited but the value of trade was not, Japanese automakers began upgrading the quality
              of their exports to raise their profitability. By the late 1980s, new higher-quality auto
              lines such as Acura, Infiniti, and Lexus made their debut. Alternatively, Japanese autos
              assembled in the US were not counted as part of the export restriction - only complete
              autos exported from Japan were restricted. Thus, after the VERs were implemented,
              Honda, Mazda, Toyota, Mitsubishi, and Nissan all opened assembly plants in the US. A
              quicker circumvention was accomplished by shipping knockdown sets (unassembled
              autos) to Taiwan and South Korea, where they were assembled and exported to the US
              market.



              International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
              Last Updated on 6/13/06
Textile VERs

              by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-3b
              Another interesting effect of VERs occurred in the textile industry beginning in the
              1950s. In the mid 50s, US cotton textile producers faced increases in Japanese exports of
              cotton textiles which negatively affected their profitability. The US government
              subsequently negotiated a VER on cotton textiles with Japan. Afterwards, textiles began
              to flood the US market from other sources like Taiwan and South Korea. The US
              government responded by negotiating VERs on cotton textiles with those countries. By
              the early 1960s, other textile producers in the US, who were producing clothing using the
              new synthetic fibers like polyester, began to experience the same problem with Japanese
              exports that cotton producers faced a few years earlier. So VERs were negotiated on
              exports of synthetic fibers from Japan to the US. During this period European textile
              producers were facing the same pressures as US producers and the EEC negotiated
              similar VERs on exports from many southeast Asian nations into the EEC.

              This process continued until its complexity led to a multilateral negotiation between the
              exporters and importers of textile products around the world. These negotiations resulted
              in the Multi-Fiber Agreement (MFA) in the early 1970s. The MFA specified quotas on
              exports from all major exporting countries to all major importing countries. Essentially it
              represented a complex arrangement of multilateral VERs. The MFA provided an assured
              upper limit (ceiling) to the extent of competition that import-competing firms could
              expect in the US and the EEC. This type of arrangement has sometimes been called an
              orderly market arrangement. It is also a reasonable example of what has been referred to
              as managed trade.

              The MFA was renewed periodically throughout the 70s, 80s and 90s. However, the
              Uruguay round of the GATT, completed in 1994, renamed the MFA to the Agreement on
              Textiles and Clothing (ATC) and specified a ten year transition period during which the
              ATC will be eliminated.



              International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
              Last Updated on 6/13/06
Export Taxes

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-4
             An export tax is a tax collected on exported goods. As with tariffs, export taxes can be
             set on a specific or an ad valorem basis. In the US, export taxes are unconstitutional
             since the US constitution contains a clause prohibiting their use. This was imposed due
             to the concerns of Southern cotton producers who exported much of their product to
             England and France.

             However, many other countries employ export taxes. For example, Indonesia applies
             taxes on palm oil exports; Madagascar applies them on vanilla, coffee, pepper and
             cloves; Russia uses export taxes on petroleum, while Brazil imposed a 40% export tax on
             sugar in 1996. In December 1995 the EU imposed a $32 per ton export tax on wheat.



             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
Export Subsidies

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-5
             Export subsidies are payments made by the government to encourage the export of
             specified products. As with taxes, subsidies can be levied on a specific or ad valorem
             basis. The most common product groups where export subsidies are applied are
             agricultural and dairy products.

             Most countries have income support programs for their nation's farmers. These are often
             motivated by national security or self-sufficiency considerations. Farmers' incomes are
             maintained by restricting domestic supply, raising domestic demand, or a combination of
             the two. One common method is the imposition of price floors on specified commodities.
             When there is excess supply at the floor price, however, the government must stand
             ready to purchase the excess. These purchases are often stored for future distribution
             when there is a shortfall of supply at the floor price. Sometimes the amount the
             government must purchase exceeds the available storage capacity. In this case, the
             government must either build more storage facilities, at some cost, or devise an
             alternative method to dispose of the surplus inventory. It is in these situations, or to avoid
             these situations, that export subsidies are sometimes used. By encouraging exports, the
             government will reduce the domestic supply and eliminate the need for the government
             to purchase the excess.

             One of the main export subsidy programs in the US is called the Export Enhancement
             Program (EEP). Its stated purpose is to help US farmers compete with farm products
             from other subsidizing countries, especially the European Union, in targeted countries.
             The EEP's major objectives are to challenge unfair trade practices, to expand U.S.
             agricultural exports, and to encourage other countries exporting agricultural commodities
             to undertake serious negotiations on agricultural trade problems. As a result of Uruguay
             round commitments, the US has established annual export subsidy quantity ceilings by
             commodity and maximum budgetary expenditures. Commodities eligible under EEP
             initiatives are wheat, wheat flour, semolina, rice, frozen poultry, frozen pork, barley,
             barley malt, table eggs, and vegetable oil.

             In recent years the US government has made annual outlays of over $1 billion in its
             agricultural Export Enhancement Program (EEP) and its Dairy Export Incentive Program
             (DEIP). The EU has spent over $4 billion annually to encourage exports of its
             agricultural and dairy products.



             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
Voluntary Import Expansions (VIEs)

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-6
             A Voluntary Import Expansion (VIE) is an agreement to increase the quantity of
             imports of a product over a specified period of time. In the late 1980s, VIEs were
             suggested by the US as a way of expanding US exports into Japanese markets. Under the
             assumption that Japan maintained barriers to trade that restricted the entry of US exports,
             Japan was asked to increase its volume of imports on specified products including
             semiconductors, automobiles, auto parts, medical equipment and flat glass. The intention
             was that VIEs would force a pattern of trade that more closely replicated the free trade
             level.



             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
Other Trade Policy Tools

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 10-7
             Government Procurement Policies
             A Government Procurement Policy requires that a specified percentage of purchases by
             the federal or state governments be made from domestic firms rather than foreign firms.


             Health and Safety Standards
             The U.S. generally has more regulations than other countries governing the use of some
             goods, such as pharmaceuticals. These regulations can have an effect upon trade patterns
             even though the policies are not designed based on their effects on trade.


             Red-Tape Barriers
             Red-tape barriers refers to costly administrative procedures required for the importation
             of foreign goods. Red-tape barriers can take many forms. France once required that
             videocassete recorders enter the country through one small port facility in the south of
             France. Because the port capacity was limited, it effectively restricted the number of
             VCRs that could enter the country. A red-tape barrier may arise if multiple licences must
             be obtained from a variety of government sources before importation of a product is
             allowed.



             International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic
             Last Updated on 5/20/99
Trade Questions Jeopardy 10-1


DIRECTIONS: As in the popular TV game show, you are given an answer to a question and you
must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is "a tax on imports," then the
correct question is "What is a tariff?"


   1. An arrangement in which a country agrees to limit the quantity of a good it
      exports to another country.
   2. A payment made by a government to encourage exports.
   3. The schedule of tariffs charged in all import commodity categories in the US.
   4. A tax levied as a dollar charge per unit of imports.
   5. A government policy which favors domestic firms over foreign firms with respect
      to government purchases.
   6. Costly or annoying administrative procedures which make it difficult to import
      goods into a country.
   7. The international organization that maintains the Harmonized Commodity Coding
      and Classification System for imported goods.
   8. A type of quota that allows a specified quantity of a good to be imported at a
      reduced tariff rate during a specified period.
   9. The new name for the multi-fiber agreement.
  10. A tax levied as a percentage of the value of an imported good.




©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
Last Updated on 6/13/06
International Trade Theory & Policy
by Steven M. Suranovic, The George Washington University

Chapter 20
Trade History and Trade Law
©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms



Table of Contents                             Problem Sets

FROM THE WTO WEBSITE                                  LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional
         What is the WTO?                             LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate
20-0
                                                      LEVEL 3: Advanced
         The WTO in Brief                             Intermediate

         Understanding the
         WTO
                                              LEVEL 1

20-1     Measuring Protectionism: Average             Jeopardy 20-1
         Tariff Rates Around the World                Internet Qs 20-1A
20-2     US Trade Policy Highlights                   Internet Qs 20-1B
 20-2a   Customs Duties in Government                 Internet Qs 20-1C
         Revenue: Britain, France and                 Internet Qs 20-1D
         Brazil                                       Problem Set 20 1-1
20-3     US Tariff Policy: Historical Notes           Problem Set 20 1-2

20-4     US Trade Law Highlights

                                              Answer Keys
DOWNLOAD Chapter 20 in PDF format.
                                                  r   Internet Explorer Download
                                                      Center

                                              Answer keys to the problem sets are for
                                              sale in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for
                                              easier viewing and printing. Purchases
                                              must be made using a recent Internet
                                              Explorer browser. Revenues from these
                                              sales will help us to expand and improve
                                              the content at this site.
Related Links
     r   WTO Trade Policy Reviews                    r   International Trade Law: An
         Trade Policy Reviews are conducted              Overview
         periodically by the WTO for every               from the Legal Information Institute
         member country. The secretariat                 at Cornell University.
         report provides a comprehensive
         summary of each country's trade             r   About the US Trade Representative
         policies.
     r   The WTO Agreements
                                                     r   About Import Administration at the
         A description of some of the details
                                                         US International Trade Admin.
         behind WTO rules on antidumping
         measures, subsidies and
         countervailing measures and                 r   About the US International Trade
         safeguards.                                     Commission



Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual
property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of
the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work
provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT
reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this
Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study
Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the
webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the
accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the
Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis.

HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE
Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Trade History and Trade Law,"
The International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/
ch20/ch20.html.
Measuring Protectionism:
             Average Tariff Rates Around the World

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 20-1   One method used to measure the degree of protectionism within an economy is the
             average tariff rate. Since tariffs generally reduce imports of foreign products, the higher
             the tariff, the greater the protection afforded to the country's import-competing
             industries. At one time, tariffs were perhaps the most commonly applied trade policy.
             Many countries used tariffs as a primary source of funds for their government budgets.
             However, as trade liberalization advanced in the second half of the twentieth century,
             many other types of non-tariff barriers became more prominent.

             The table below provides a list of average tariff rates in selected countries around the
             world. These rates were all taken from the WTO's trade policy review summaries. More
             details about the trade policies of these countries can be found at the WTO's website at:
             http://www.wto.org/wto/reviews/tp.htm.

             Generally speaking, average tariff rates are less than 20% in most countries, although
             they are often quite a bit higher for agricultural commodities. In the most developed
             countries, average tariffs are less than 10%, and often less than 5%. On average, less
             developed countries maintain higher tariff barriers, but, for many countries that have
             recently joined the WTO, tariffs have recently been reduced substantially to gain entry.


                               Average Tariff Rates

              Japan (1997)                              9.4%

              European Union (1997)
                                                        4.9%
                       Industrial Goods
                                                       20.8%
                       Agriculture


              Norway (1996)                             5.6%

              Canada (1996)
                                                        6.6%
                       Overall
                                                        1.0%
                       with US


              Brazil (1996)                            12.5%
Mexico (1997)

                                            13.2%
         Overall
                                             4.2%
         With US


 Chile (1997)                               11.0%

 El Salvador (1995)                         10.1%

 Cyprus (1996)
                                            16.4%
         Overall
                                             7.2%
         with EU
                                            37.6%
         Agriculture


 Morocco (1995)                             23.5%

 Benin (1997)                               13.0%

 Zambia (1996)                              13.6%

 Malaysia (1997)                             8.1%

 Thailand (1994)                            30.0%


Problems Using Average Tariffs as a Measure of Protection

The first problem with using average tariffs as a measure of protection in a country is
that there are several different ways to calculate an average tariff rate and each method
can give a very different impression about the level of protection.

Most of the tariffs above are calculated as a simple average. To calculate this rate, one
simply adds up all of the tariff rates and divides by the number of import categories. One
problem with this method arises if a country has most of its trade in a few categories with
zero tariffs, but has high tariffs in many import categories in which it would never find
advantageous to import. In this case the average tariff may overstate the degree of
protection in the economy.

This problem can be avoided, to a certain extent, if one calculates the trade-weighted
average tariff. This measure weights each tariff by the share of total imports in that
import category. Thus, if a country has most of its imports in a category with very low
tariffs, but has many import categories with high tariffs but virtually no imports, then the
trade-weighted average tariff would indicate a low level of protection. The standard way
of calculating this tariff rate is to divide total tariff revenue by the total value of imports.
Since this data is regularly reported by many countries this is a common way to report
average tariffs.

However, the trade-weighted average tariff is not without flaws. As an example, suppose
a country has relatively little trade because it has prohibitive tariffs (i.e. tariffs set so high
as to eliminate imports) in many import categories. If it has some trade in a few import
categories with relatively low tariffs, then the trade-weighted average tariff would be
relatively low. After all, there would be no tariff revenue in the categories with
prohibitive tariffs. In this case, a low average tariff could be reported for a highly
protectionist country. Note also that, in this case, the simple average tariff would register
a higher average tariff and might be a better indicator of the level of protection in the
economy.

Of course the best way to overstate the degree of protection is to use the average tariff
rate on dutiable imports. This alternative measure, which is sometimes reported, only
considers categories in which a tariff is actually levied and ignores all categories in
which the tariff is set to zero. Since many countries today have many categories of goods
with zero tariffs applied, this measure would give a higher estimate of average tariffs
than most of the other measures.(1)

The second major problem with using average tariff rates to measure the degree of
protection is that tariffs are not the only trade policy used by countries. Countries also
implement quotas, import licenses, voluntary export restraints, export taxes, export
subsidies, government procurement policies, domestic content rules, and much more. In
addition, there are a variety of domestic regulations which, for large economies at least,
can and do have an impact on trade flows. None of these regulations, restrictions or
impediments to trade, affecting both imports and exports, would be captured using any of
the average tariff measures. Nevertheless these non-tariff barriers can have a much
greater effect upon trade flows than tariffs themselves.

The Ideal Measure of Protectionism

Ideally, what we would like to measure is the degree to which a government's policies
(both domestic and trade policies) affect the flow of goods and services (on both the
import and export side) between itself and the rest of the world. Thus, we might imagine
an index of protectionism (IP) defined as follows:




Where the numerator represents the sum of all exports and imports across all N trade
categories given the current set of trade policies, and the denominator represents the
sum of all exports and imports that would obtain if the government employed a set of
domestic policies that had no impact on trade of goods and services with the rest of the
world. If IP = 1, it would indicate that current government policies are completely non-
restrictive and the economy could be characterized as being in a pure state of "free
trade." If IP = 0, then government policies would be so restrictive as to force the
economy into a state of isolation or autarky.

If we could calculate and compare the index across many countries, then we could say
that countries with a smaller value were more protectionist than countries with a higher
value. We could also monitor changes in the index over time for a particular country.
Increases in the index value would indicate trade liberalization, while decreases in the
index would indicate growing protectionism.

The problem with this index, however, is that although it is easy to define, it would be
virtually impossible to measure. At least, I know of no way of doing so without making
extreme leaps of faith. Nevertheless, the index definition is useful as a way of indicating
how far from ideal are any traditional measures of protection such as average tariff rates.




Endnotes:

1. It is often claimed that average tariffs in the US were raised to almost 60% by the
Smoot-Hawley tariff act of 1930. This figure, although correct, represents the average
tariff on dutiable imports only. Thus, the figure somewhat overstates the true degree of
protection. In comparison, the trade-weighted average tariff in subsequent years rose
only as high as 24.8% in 1932, after which tariff rates fell.




©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
Last Updated on 6/14/06
US Trade Policy Highlights

             by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 20-2   Article 1, section 8 of the US Constitution states clearly and succinctly: " the Congress
             shall have the power ... to regulate commerce with foreign nations ..." This means that
             decisions about trade policy must be made by the US Senate and House of
             Representatives, and not by the US President.

             This clause is rather interesting today because one of the key agencies involved in US
             trade negotiations is the US Trade Representative's office. This office administers the
             Section 301 trade cases, has negotiated free trade agreements such as NAFTA, and has
             negotiated trade liberalization agreements such as the Uruguay round under the GATT.
             All this from an Executive branch agency which acts as an agent for the President. It
             would seem, then, that the President does indeed make trade policy. Is this a violation of
             the constitution? Actually no.

             The only reason an Executive branch agency, like USTR, can make trade policy is
             because the US Congress has granted this agency the authority to do so. This issue was
             in the news recently when the Clinton administration attempted, unsuccessfully (as of
             Feb 1998), to acquire fast track negotiating authority for new free trade agreements with
             other countries. Fast track authority would not only give the President and his agents
             negotiating powers; it would also require the US Congress to vote on any trade
             agreement presented by the President without amendment. This means that Congress
             must vote "yea" or "nay" to the entire agreement and cannot make changes to it before
             the vote. The purpose of fast track authority is to give more credibility to the President
             and his agents in negotiations with other countries, and hence raise the likelihood that an
             agreement can be reached.

             Probably one reason that the framers of the US Constitution reserved trade policy
             formation for the US Congress was because at the time of US independence and for well
             over a century after that, tariff revenue was the primary source of funds for the federal
             government. It must have been thought unwise for the purse strings of the government to
             be controlled by the President.
The adjoining diagram shows US customs duties as a percentage of federal government
revenue from 1821 to 1996. Notice that in the early 1800s tariff revenue comprised more
than 90% of the federal government budget. This fell during and after the US Civil War
in 1860 as alternative sources of funds became necessary to finance the war. Another
major decline occurred in the early part of the 1900s shortly after the Constitution was
amended to allow the collection of personal income taxes. In the 1990s, more than 70%
of federal government revenue came from payroll taxes which consists of both personal
income taxes and social security taxes. In contrast, less than 1.5% of revenue came from
customs duties. Of course, due to the size of the US federal budget, that still amounts to
over $18 billion in tariff revenue.

Comparisons with Other Countries

Often it is informative to compare one country's experience with others during the same
period. Click on the country below to see graphs showing customs duties as a percentage
of government revenue in Britain (1821 - 1964), France (1847 - 1988), and Brazil (1937
- 1985).




©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
Last Updated on 6/14/06
Customs Duties in Government Revenue: Britain, France
              and Brazil

              by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006


Trade 20-2a   These graphs depict customs duties as a percentage of federal government revenue in
              Britain (1821 - 1964), France (1847 - 1988), and Brazil (1937 - 1985). Note that both
              Britain and France collected a much smaller percentage of government revenue from
              customs duties in the 1800s compared with the US. In France it was significantly lower
              and not much different from what prevails in there today. The pattern is Brazil is very
              similar to the path followed by the US after 1940.
©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
Last Updated on 6/14/06
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006
Intl trade suranovic-2006

More Related Content

Similar to Intl trade suranovic-2006

International business mumbai university solved paper 2008
International business mumbai university solved paper 2008International business mumbai university solved paper 2008
International business mumbai university solved paper 2008shrund
 
Global HR Practices
Global HR PracticesGlobal HR Practices
Global HR PracticesPratik Patel
 
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docxjackiewalcutt
 
Deepak ib solved paper
Deepak ib solved paperDeepak ib solved paper
Deepak ib solved paperDeepak R Gorad
 
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A D
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A DWriting An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A D
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A DBeth Johnson
 
Globalization (1)
Globalization (1)Globalization (1)
Globalization (1)mzk57
 
Ba7401 international business management
Ba7401 international business managementBa7401 international business management
Ba7401 international business managementMonica Purushothaman
 
International finance 315_v1
International finance 315_v1International finance 315_v1
International finance 315_v1Aman Tiwari
 
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAs
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAsMD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAs
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAsAbramMartino96
 
Ib0017 – international business environment and international law
Ib0017 – international business environment and international lawIb0017 – international business environment and international law
Ib0017 – international business environment and international lawsmumbahelp
 
Ba7401 international business_management
Ba7401 international business_managementBa7401 international business_management
Ba7401 international business_managementBhubaneswari Bisoyi
 
Instructor’s Resource Manual For Multination.docx
Instructor’s Resource Manual   For Multination.docxInstructor’s Resource Manual   For Multination.docx
Instructor’s Resource Manual For Multination.docxbagotjesusa
 
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docx
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docxI need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docx
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docxtroutmanboris
 
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Stephen Ong
 
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)Neeraj Bhandari
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1AaryanAJirde
 
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)Osama Elaish
 

Similar to Intl trade suranovic-2006 (20)

International business mumbai university solved paper 2008
International business mumbai university solved paper 2008International business mumbai university solved paper 2008
International business mumbai university solved paper 2008
 
International Trade & Business
International Trade & Business International Trade & Business
International Trade & Business
 
Global HR Practices
Global HR PracticesGlobal HR Practices
Global HR Practices
 
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx
1. Please visit the following link on the Economist.com and an.docx
 
Deepak ib solved paper
Deepak ib solved paperDeepak ib solved paper
Deepak ib solved paper
 
Introduction of international trade
Introduction of international tradeIntroduction of international trade
Introduction of international trade
 
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A D
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A DWriting An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A D
Writing An Descriptive Essays - How To Write A D
 
Globalization (1)
Globalization (1)Globalization (1)
Globalization (1)
 
Ba7401 international business management
Ba7401 international business managementBa7401 international business management
Ba7401 international business management
 
International finance 315_v1
International finance 315_v1International finance 315_v1
International finance 315_v1
 
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAs
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAsMD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAs
MD4099 Assessment 1 – Individual EssayDetails of assessmentAs
 
Ib0017 – international business environment and international law
Ib0017 – international business environment and international lawIb0017 – international business environment and international law
Ib0017 – international business environment and international law
 
Ba7401 international business_management
Ba7401 international business_managementBa7401 international business_management
Ba7401 international business_management
 
Instructor’s Resource Manual For Multination.docx
Instructor’s Resource Manual   For Multination.docxInstructor’s Resource Manual   For Multination.docx
Instructor’s Resource Manual For Multination.docx
 
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docx
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docxI need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docx
I need a 125 word reply to each of the four following forum postings.docx
 
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
 
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)
International Trade and Policy- Introduction by Neeraj Bhandari (Surkhet Nepal)
 
Chapter1 IFM
Chapter1 IFMChapter1 IFM
Chapter1 IFM
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1
 
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)
Is Foreign Ownership Beneficial for Creating Value -Seminar in Finance Paper (1)
 

More from Thorat Pravin

Advertisement modified 02012012
Advertisement modified 02012012Advertisement modified 02012012
Advertisement modified 02012012Thorat Pravin
 
Principles and practices of banking
Principles and practices of bankingPrinciples and practices of banking
Principles and practices of bankingThorat Pravin
 
Generalinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheet
GeneralinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheetGeneralinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheet
GeneralinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheetThorat Pravin
 
Approval process handbook_091012
Approval process handbook_091012Approval process handbook_091012
Approval process handbook_091012Thorat Pravin
 
Application report 2013-2014-user_manual
Application report 2013-2014-user_manualApplication report 2013-2014-user_manual
Application report 2013-2014-user_manualThorat Pravin
 
Anti ragging affidavit
Anti ragging affidavitAnti ragging affidavit
Anti ragging affidavitThorat Pravin
 
Academic caleder 2013 new
Academic caleder 2013 newAcademic caleder 2013 new
Academic caleder 2013 newThorat Pravin
 
Application deficiency report_13-14 1
Application deficiency report_13-14 1Application deficiency report_13-14 1
Application deficiency report_13-14 1Thorat Pravin
 
Women harrasment cell
Women harrasment cellWomen harrasment cell
Women harrasment cellThorat Pravin
 
Guide recognisation form
Guide recognisation formGuide recognisation form
Guide recognisation formThorat Pravin
 

More from Thorat Pravin (16)

D pharm syllabus
D pharm syllabusD pharm syllabus
D pharm syllabus
 
320 el3
320 el3320 el3
320 el3
 
Advertisement modified 02012012
Advertisement modified 02012012Advertisement modified 02012012
Advertisement modified 02012012
 
Admission starategu
Admission starateguAdmission starategu
Admission starategu
 
Principles and practices of banking
Principles and practices of bankingPrinciples and practices of banking
Principles and practices of banking
 
Document1
Document1Document1
Document1
 
Generalinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheet
GeneralinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheetGeneralinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheet
Generalinstructionsforfillingfacultyexcelsheet
 
Approval process handbook_091012
Approval process handbook_091012Approval process handbook_091012
Approval process handbook_091012
 
Application report 2013-2014-user_manual
Application report 2013-2014-user_manualApplication report 2013-2014-user_manual
Application report 2013-2014-user_manual
 
Anti ragging affidavit
Anti ragging affidavitAnti ragging affidavit
Anti ragging affidavit
 
Academic caleder 2013 new
Academic caleder 2013 newAcademic caleder 2013 new
Academic caleder 2013 new
 
Paper adv1
Paper adv1Paper adv1
Paper adv1
 
Application deficiency report_13-14 1
Application deficiency report_13-14 1Application deficiency report_13-14 1
Application deficiency report_13-14 1
 
Women harrasment cell
Women harrasment cellWomen harrasment cell
Women harrasment cell
 
Test 2
Test 2Test 2
Test 2
 
Guide recognisation form
Guide recognisation formGuide recognisation form
Guide recognisation form
 

Intl trade suranovic-2006

  • 1. International Trade Theory and Policy Analysis by Steven Suranovic The George Washington University ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the webmaster@internationalecon. com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis.
  • 2. International Trade Theory & Policy by Steven M. Suranovic Chapter 5 Introductory Issues ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms Table of Contents Problem Sets The International Economy LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional 5-1 LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate 5-2 What is International LEVEL 3: Advanced Intermediate Economics? 5-3 Brief Outline LEVEL 1 5-4 Some Trade Terminology 5-5 Valuable Lessons of Jeopardy 5-1 International Trade Theory 5-5A Lesson A 5-5B Lesson B Answer Keys 5-5C Lesson C r Internet Explorer Download 5-5D Lesson D Center 5-5E Lesson E 5-5F Lesson F Answer keys to the problem sets are for sale in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for easier viewing and printing. Purchases must be DOWNLOAD Chapter 5 in PDF format. made using a recent Internet Explorer browser. Revenues from these sales will help us to expand and improve the content at this site. Related Links r Deardorff's Glossary of International r Think Again: International Trade Economics Article by Arvind Panagariya that Alan Deardorff's (UMichigan) highlights some important collection of citations and definitions regularities about international trade. regarding international economics. Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT
  • 3. reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis. HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Introductory Issues," The International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch5/ ch5.html.
  • 4. The International Economy by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2007 Trade 5-1 International economics is growing in importance as a field of study because of the rapid integration of international economic markets. More and more, businesses, consumers and governments realize that their lives are increasingly affected, not just by what goes on in their own town, state or country, but by what is happening around the world. Consumers can buy goods and services from all over the world in their local shops. Local businesses must compete with these foreign products. However, these same businesses also have new opportunities to expand their markets by selling in a multitude of other countries. The advance of telecommunications is rapidly reducing the cost of providing services internationally and the internet will assuredly change the nature of many products and services as it expands markets even further than today. Markets have been going global, and everyone knows it. One simple way to see this is to look at the growth of exports in the world during the past 50+ years. The following figure shows overall annual exports measured in billions of US dollars from 1948 to 2005. Recognizing that one country's exports are another country's imports, one can see the exponential growth in trade during the past 50 years.
  • 5. However, rapid growth in the value of exports does not necessarily indicate that trade is becoming more important. Instead, one needs to look at the share of traded goods in relation to the size of the world economy. The adjoining figure shows world exports as a percentage of world GDP for the years 1970 to 2005. It shows a steady increase in trade as a share of the size of the world economy. World exports grew from just over 10% of GDP in 1970 to almost 30% by 2005. Thus, trade is not only rising rapidly in absolute terms, it is becoming relatively more important too. One other indicator of world interconnectedness can be seen in changes in the amount of foreign direct investment (FDI). FDI is foreign ownership of productive activities and thus is another way in which foreign economic influence can affect a country. The adjoining figure shows the stock, or the sum total value, of FDI around the world taken as a percentage of world GDP between 1980 and 2004. It gives an indication of the importance of foreign ownership and influence around the world. As can be seen, the share of FDI has grown dramatically from around 5% of world GDP in 1980 to over 20% of GDP just 25 years later.
  • 6. The growth of international trade and investment has been stimulated partly by the steady decline of trade barriers since the Great Depression of the 1930s. In the post World War II era the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, or GATT, was an agreement that prompted regular negotiations among a growing body of members to reduce tariffs (import taxes) on imported goods on a reciprocal basis. During each of these regular negotiations, (eight of these rounds were completed between 1948 and 1994), countries promised to reduce their tariffs on imports in exchange for concessions, or tariffs reductions, by other GATT members. When the most recent completed round was finished in 1994, the member countries succeeded in extending the agreement to include liberalization promises in a much larger sphere of influence. Now countries would not only lower tariffs on goods trade, but would begin to liberalize agriculture and services market. They would eliminate the many quota systems - like the multi-fiber agreement in clothing - that had sprouted up in previous decades. And they would agree to adhere to certain minimum standards to protect intellectual property rights such as patents, trademarks and copyrights. The WTO was created to manage this system of new agreements, to provide a forum for regular discussion of trade matters and to implement a well-defined process for settling trade disputes that might arise among countries. As of 2006, 149 countries were members of the WTO "trade liberalization club" and many more countries were still negotiating entry. As the club grows to include more members, and if the latest round of trade liberalization discussion called the Doha round concludes with an agreement, world markets will become increasingly open to trade and investment. [Note: the Doha round of discussions was begun in 2001 and remains uncompleted as of 2006] Another international push for trade liberalization has come in the form of regional free trade agreements. Over 200 regional trade agreements around the world have been notified, or announced, to the WTO. Many countries
  • 7. have negotiated these with neighboring countries or major trading partners, to promote even faster trade liberalization. In part these have arisen because of the slow, plodding pace of liberalization under the GATT/WTO. In part it has occurred because countries have wished to promote interdependence and connectedness with important economic or strategic trade partners. In any case, the phenomenon serves to open international markets even further than achieved in the WTO. These changes in economic patterns and the trend towards ever increasing openness are an important aspect of the more exhaustive phenomenon known as globalization. Globalization more formally refers to the economic, social, cultural or environmental changes that tend to interconnect peoples around the world. Since the economic aspects of globalization are certainly one of the most pervasive of these changes, it is increasingly important to understand the implications of a global marketplace on consumers, businesses and governments. That is where the study of international economics begins. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2007 Steven M. Suranovic . Last Updated on 12/24/06
  • 8. What is International Economics? by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-2 International economics is a field of study which assesses the implications of international trade in goods and services and international investment. There are two broad sub-fields within international economics: international trade and international finance. International trade is a field in economics that applies microeconomic models to help understand the international economy. Its content includes the same tools that are introduced in microeconomics courses, including supply and demand analysis, firm and consumer behavior, perfectly competitive, oligopolistic and monopolistic market structures, and the effects of market distortions. The typical course describes economic relationships between consumers, firms, factor owners, and the government. The objective of an international trade course is to understand the effects on individuals and businesses because of international trade itself, because of changes in trade policies and due to changes in other economic conditions. The course will develop arguments that support a free trade policy as well as arguments that support various types of protectionist policies. By the end of the course, students should better understand the centuries-old controversy between free trade and protectionism. International finance applies macroeconomic models to help understand the international economy. Its focus is on the interrelationships between aggregate economic variables such as GDP, unemployment rates, inflation rates, trade balances, exchange rates, interest rates, etc. This field expands macroeconomics to include international exchanges. Its focus is on the significance of trade imbalances, the determinants of exchange rates and the aggregate effects of government monetary and fiscal policies. Among the most important issues addressed are the pros and cons of fixed versus floating exchange rate systems. [Note: A separate collection of web materials on international finance is available at The International Finance Webtext]. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 7/17/04
  • 9. Brief Outline by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-3 The course is divided into four distinct sections. 1. International Trade History and Current Issues q The Terminology of International Trade q Trade Policy Instruments q Trade History q Current Trade Issues 2. The Effects of International Trade In this section a variety of models are developed which highlight the following five basic reasons that trade occurs. q differences in technology q differences in resource endowments q differences in consumer demand q existence of economics of scale in production q existence of government policies The models address the effects that trade has on the prices of goods and services, the profits of firms, the well-being of consumers, the wages of workers, and the return to other factors of production. 3. The Effects of Trade Policies These models address the effects that trade policies have on the prices of goods and services, the profits of firms, the well-being of consumers, the wages of workers, the return to other factors of production and the implications for the government budget. This section is divided according to the following assumptions on market structure. 1. Perfect Competition 2. Market Imperfections and Distortions
  • 10. 4. Evaluating the Controversy: Free Trade or Protectionism? This final section reviews the results of the course by applying them to the premier controversy in international trade: whether to follow a policy of free trade or selected protectionism. Using trade theory results, we develop the arguments that support a policy of free trade and the arguments that support a policy of selected protectionism. We also provide the counter-arguments or caveats that can be used against each of the arguments supporting a particular position. In the end, the section does not reach a definitive conclusion. It is left to the reader to decide which arguments carry the greatest validity. However, the argument does "tilt" in the direction of free trade. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 7/17/04
  • 11. Some Trade Terminology by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-4 In trade policy discussions terms such as protectionism, free trade, and trade liberalization are used repeatedly. It is worthwhile to define these terms at the beginning. One other term is commonly used in the analysis of trade models, namely national autarky, or just autarky. Two extreme states or conditions could potentially be created by national government policies. At one extreme, a government could pursue a "laissez faire" policy with respect to trade and thus impose no regulation whatsoever that would impede (or encourage) the free voluntary exchange of goods between nations. We define this condition as free trade. At the other extreme, a government could impose such restrictive regulations on trade as to eliminate all incentive for international trade. We define this condition in which no international trade occurs as national autarky. Autarky represents a state of isolationism. (See Figure). Probably, a pure state of free trade or autarky has never existed in the real world. All nations impose some form of trade policies. And probably no government has ever had such complete control over economic activity as to eliminate cross-border trade entirely. The real world, instead, consists of countries that fall somewhere between these two extremes. Some countries, such as Singapore and (formerly) Hong Kong, are considered to be highly free trade oriented. Others, like North Korea and Cuba, have long been relatively closed economies and thus are closer to the state of autarky. The rest of the world lies somewhere in between. Most policy discussions are not about whether governments should pursue one of these two extremes. Instead, discussions focus on which direction a country should move along the trade spectrum. Since every country today is somewhere in the middle, discussions focus on whether policies should move the nation in the direction of free trade or in the direction of autarky. A movement in the direction of autarky occurs whenever a new trade policy is implemented if it further restricts the free flow of goods and services between countries. Since new trade policies invariably benefit domestic industries by reducing international competition, it is also referred to as protectionism.
  • 12. A movement in the direction of free trade occurs when regulations on trade are removed. Since the elimination of trade policies will generally increase the amount of international trade, it is referred to as trade liberalization. Trade policy discussions typically focus, then, on whether the country should increase protectionism or whether it should pursue trade liberalization. Note that, according to this definition of protectionism, even policies that encourage trade, such as export subsidies, are considered protectionist since they alter the pattern of trade that would have prevailed in the absence of government intervention. This implies that protectionism is much more complex than can be represented along a single dimension (as suggested in the above diagram) since protection can both increase and decrease trade flows. Nevertheless, the representation of the trade spectrum is useful in a number of ways. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/12/06
  • 13. Valuable Lessons of International Trade Theory by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5 In this section some of the most important lessons in international trade theory are briefly presented. Often, the lessons that are most interesting and valuable are those that teach something either counterintuitive, or at least contrary to popular opinions. A number of these are represented below. Each explanation also provides links to the pages where the arguments are more fully explained. (Note: For most students, following the links initially may be more confusing than helpful. However, once reading through many of the chapters, review of these lessons may help reinforce them). A. The main support for free trade arises because free trade can raise aggregate economic efficiency. B. Trade theory shows that some people will suffer losses in free trade. C. A country may benefit from free trade even if it is less efficient than all other countries in every industry. D. A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is the lowest-cost producer in the world. E. Protection may be beneficial for a country. F. Although protection can be beneficial, the case for free trade remains strong. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 14. Lesson 5A by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5A The main support for free trade arises because free trade can raise aggregate economic efficiency. In most models of trade there is an improvement in aggregate efficiency when an economy moves from autarky to free trade. This is the same as an increase in national welfare. Efficiency improvements can be decomposed into two separate effects: production efficiency and consumption efficiency. An improvement in production efficiency means that countries can produce more goods and services with the same amount of resources. In other words, productivity rises for the given resource endowments available for use in production. Consumption efficiency improvements mean, in essence, that consumers will have a more satisfying collection of goods and services from which to choose. Many economists define the objective of the economics discipline as seeking to identify the best way to use scarce resources to satisfy the needs and wants of the people of a country. Economic efficiency is the term economists use to formally measure this objective. Since free trade tends to promote economic efficiency is so many models, this is one of the strongest arguments in support of free trade. This result is formally demonstrated in the Ricardian model (see page 40-9b), the Immobile Factor model (see page 70-15), the Specific Factor model, the Heckscher- Ohlin model (see page 60-10), the Demand Difference model, the simple Economies of Scale model, (see page 80-3) and the Monopolistic Competition model (see page 80-5e). It can also be demonstrated when a small country reduces barriers to trade (Consider the analysis on page 90-11 in reverse). Each of these models shows that a country can have a larger national output (i.e. GDP) and superior choices available in consumption as a result of free trade. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 15. Lesson 5B by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5B Trade theory shows that some people will suffer losses in free trade. A common misperception about international economics is that it teaches that everyone will benefit from free trade. One often hears that voluntary exchange, whether between individuals or between nations, must benefit both parties to the transaction, otherwise the transaction would not occur. Although this argument is valid for exchange between two people, the conclusion changes when one considers two countries made up of multiple individuals. (See pages 30-3 through 30-5) Economists themselves often espouse the position that free trade is beneficial to all, albeit often with the caveat, "... at least in the long run". In the short run, factors of production may be relatively immobile across industries (see pages 70-1 and 70-2). In the presence of immobility, it can be shown that while export industries would gain from free trade, import-competing industries would lose (see page 70-17). Thus, in the short run, resource adjustment problems can explain losses to some groups. In the long run, once all resources can move to alternative industries, some models (e.g. Ricardian) suggest that everyone in the economy would benefit from free trade (See page 40-9a). Other models (e.g. Heckscher-Ohlin) however, suggest that some groups may continue to lose even in the long run (See page 60-12). Another complication is that not everyone will make it to the long run. As John Maynard Keynes once remarked, "In the long run, we are all dead." If not dead, it is surely true that some individuals will retire from the labor force before the long run arrives. These individuals may be unfortunate enough to experience only the negative short-run losses to an industry. Upon retirement, their short-term losses may carry over to long-run losses. Economists will often dismiss concerns about potential losses from trade liberalization by proposing that compensation be provided. The "compensation principle" suggests that some of the gains could be taken away from the winners and given to the losers such that everyone becomes better-off as a result of free trade. Although the principle is valid conceptually, effective implementation of it seems unlikely (See discussion on page 60-13). International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 16. Lesson 5C by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5C A country may benefit from free trade even if it is less efficient than all other countries in every industry. It makes sense that one firm would be more successful than another firm in a local market if it could produce its output more efficiently - that is at lower cost - than the second firm. If the two firms produce identical products, then the less efficient firm is likely to be driven out of business, generating losses. If we extend this example to an international market then it would also make sense that a more efficient foreign firm would absorb business from a less efficient domestic firm. Finally, suppose all firms in all industries domestically were less efficient than all firms in all industries in the foreign countries. It would then seem logically impossible for any domestic firms to succeed in competition in the international market with the foreign firms. International competition would seemingly have only negative effects upon the less efficient domestic firms and the domestic country. This seemingly logical conclusion is refuted by the Ricardian model of comparative advantage. Ricardo demonstrated the surprising result that less efficient firms in a country can indeed compete with foreign firms in international markets. In addition, by moving to free trade, the less efficient country can generate welfare improvements for everybody in the country. Free trade can even benefit a country that is less efficient at producing everything (See page 40-9). What's more, in a free market system, differences in prices and profit-seeking behavior are all that is needed to induce countries to produce and export the "right" goods and trade to their national benefit. (see especially 40-8) International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 17. Lesson 5D by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5D A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is the lowest-cost producer in the world. This result is a corollary of Lesson 3. As argued there, it seems reasonable to think that a more efficient firm (i.e., one who produces at lower cost) would drive its less efficient competitors out of business. The same would seem to follow if the two firms are domestic and foreign and the two firms compete in international markets. However, the Ricardian model of comparative advantage argues that a firm in one country, even if it is the lowest-cost producer in the world, may be forced out of business once the country liberalizes trade with the rest of the world. Even more surprising, despite the decline of this industry, the move to free trade can generate welfare improvements for everybody in the country. In other words, losing production in a highly efficient industry can be consistent with an improvement in welfare for everyone. This contradicts the logic above which would suggest that more efficient (lower-cost) firms should always win (See page 40-9). It is important to note that this result does not imply that every decline of an efficient industry will improve welfare. Instead, the model merely suggests that one should not jump to the conclusion that the loss of an efficient industry will have negative effects for the country as a whole. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 18. Lesson 5E by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5E Protection may be beneficial for a country. Sometimes the support for free trade by economists seems so strong that one might think there is very little evidence to suggest that protection could be beneficial. In actuality, there are numerous examples in the trade literature which show that protection can be beneficial for a country. The examples fall into two categories. The first category contains trade policies which raise domestic national welfare, but which reduce aggregate world welfare at the same time. These type of policies are sometimes called "beggar-thy-neighbor" policies since benefits to one country can only arise by forcing losses upon its trading partners. The most notable example is the terms of trade argument for protection which is valid whenever a country is either a large importer or a large exporter of a product in international markets (See page 90-9). A second type of beggar-thy-neighbor policy is strategic trade policy. These policies benefit the domestic country by shifting profit away from either foreign firms or foreign consumers (See pages 100-5). The second category of beneficial trade policies are those which not only raise domestic welfare but raise world welfare as well. Some trade policies may act to correct prevailing market imperfections or distortions. If the welfare improvement caused by correcting the imperfection or distortion exceeds any additional distortion caused by the trade policy, then world welfare may rise. Many well-known justifications for protection, including the potential for unemployment (see page 100-3), infant industries (see page 100-4), the presence of foreign monopolies, (see page 100-5) and concern for national security (see page 100-7), arise because of the assumption of market imperfections or distortions. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 19. Lesson 5F by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 5-5F Although protection can be beneficial, the case for free trade remains strong. The argument in support of free trade is often different depending on whether the speaker is in a political setting or an academic setting. In a political setting, political realities will often force the speaker to emphasize all of the positive aspects of free trade and to hardly even mention any negative aspects. The reason for this is that talking of the negative effects of free trade will offer up ammunition to one's opponents who may then use these statements against him in future debates. Since most people will have learned the argument for free trade by listening to political and public policy debates in the news media, they are likely to believe that economics teaches that free trade is good for all people, in all countries, at all times. This belief may lead people, especially those obviously hurt by freer trade policies, to doubt whether economics has anything useful to say about the real world. However, the academic argument for free trade, is much more sophisticated than the typical political argument. As readers of this site will learn, free trade will cause harm to some (see 5-5b), as well as good to others. Furthermore, certain selected protectionist policies can be good for individuals, and for the nation (see 5-5e), but they will also cause harm as well. Thus, the choice between free trade and selected protection is not as simple as typically presented by political advocates on one side or the other. In essence, one must choose between the good and bad that comes with free trade, and the good and bad that comes with selected protectionism. In weighing the alternatives, economists often conclude that free trade is the more pragmatic choice, dominating, for a variety of reasons, selected protectionist policies. This more sophisticated argument for free trade is the topic of Chapter 120. The chapter highlights both the positive and negative aspects of free trade policies and refers readers back via hyperlinks to many sections in the main text to support each argument. Chapter 120 is useful to read at the beginning of your studies to see where the course is going. It is even more important to read at the end, to see how everything covered in the text fits into the argument supporting free trade. During this second reading, the hyperlinks will become especially useful. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic. Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 20. Trade Questions Jeopardy 5-1 DIRECTIONS: As in the popular TV game show, you are given an answer to a question and you must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is "a tax on imports," then the correct question is "What is a tariff?" 1. Of micro- or macro-economics, the one whose methods are mostly applied in an international trade theory course. 2. Of micro- or macro-economics, the one whose methods are mostly applied in an international finance theory course. 3. Term of French origin used to describe a total absence of government regulation. 4. Term used to describe a situation in which a country does not trade with any other country. 5. The two types of economic efficiency. 6. Term given to the principle of redistribution between winners and losers. 7. Name of the economist who once remarked, "In the long run, we are all dead!" 8. Term used to describe policies which raise domestic welfare while reducing welfare in the rest of the world. 9. Name given to a policy that shifts profits away from foreign firms towards the domestic economy. 10. The premier controversy in international trade policy analysis. ©2000-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 21. International Trade Theory & Policy by Steven M. Suranovic Chapter 10 Trade Policy Tools ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms Table of Contents Problem Sets Chapter Overview LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional 10-0 LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate 10-1 Import Tariffs LEVEL 3: Advanced Intermediate 10-1a US Tariffs - 2004 10-2 Import Quotas LEVEL 1 10-3 Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs) Jeopardy 10-1 10-3a US-Japan Automobile VERs 10-3b Textile VERs Answer Keys 10-4 Export Taxes r Internet Explorer Download 10-5 Export Subsidies Center 10-6 Voluntary Import Expansions (VIEs) Answer keys to the problem sets are for sale 10-7 Other Trade Policy Tools in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for easier viewing and printing. Purchases must be made using a recent Internet Explorer DOWNLOAD Chapter 10 in PDF format. browser. Revenues from these sales will help us to expand and improve the content at this site.
  • 22. Related Links r All About Textiles and Clothing and the WTO This page at the WTO website r Tariff Rate Quota Administration provides a gateway to all sorts of A briefing paper by the Economic information about textile and Research Service at the US Dept. of clothing agreements. Agriculture r Agricultural Export Subsidies r South African Customs Tariffs Overview Updated Weekly Another briefing paper by the r Newly Independent States: Tariff Economic Research Service at the Schedules US Dept. of Agriculture This page provides links to tariffs r Tariffication and Tariff Reduction schedules for many of the Newly Another briefing paper by the Independent States. Economic Research Service at the r APEC Country: Tariff Schedules US Dept. of Agriculture This page provides links to tariffs schedules for many of the APEC countries. (You may need to register. It is free). Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis. HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Introductory Issues," The International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch10/ ch10.html.
  • 23. Trade Policy Tools by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-0 Trade policies come in many varieties. Generally they consist of either taxes or subsidies, quantitative restrictions or encouragements, on either imported or exported goods, services and assets. In this section we describe many of the policies that countries have implemented or have proposed implementing. For each policy we present examples of their use in the US or in other countries. The purpose of this section is not to explain the likely effects of each policy, but rather to define and describe the use of each policy. q Import Tariffs q Import Quotas q Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs) q Export Taxes q Export Subsidies q Voluntary Import Expansions (VIEs) q Other Trade Policies International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 24. Import Tariffs by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-1 An import tariff is a tax collected on imported goods. Generally speaking, a tariff is any tax or fee collected by a government. Sometimes tariff is used in a non-trade context, as in railroad tariffs. However, the term is much more commonly applied to a tax on imported goods. There are two basic ways in which tariffs may be levied: specific tariffs and ad valorem tariffs. A specific tariff is levied as a fixed charge per unit of imports. For example, the US government levies a 5.1 cent specific tariff on every wristwatch imported into the US. Thus, if 1000 watches are imported, the US government collects $51 in tariff revenue. In this case, $51 is collected whether the watch is a $40 Swatch or a $5000 Rolex. An ad valorem tariff is levied as a fixed percentage of the value of the commodity imported. "Ad valorem" is Latin for "on value" or "in proportion to the value." The US currently levies a 2.5% ad valorem tariff on imported automobiles. Thus if $100,000 worth of autos are imported, the US government collects $2,500 in tariff revenue. In this case, $2500 is collected whether two $50,000 BMWs are imported or ten $10,000 Hyundais. Occasionally both a specific and an ad valorem tariff are levied on the same product simultaneously. This is known as a two-part tariff. For example, wristwatches imported into the US face the 5.1 cent specific tariff as well as a 6.25% ad valorem tariff on the case and the strap and a 5.3% ad valorem tariff on the battery. Perhaps this should be called a three-part tariff! As the above examples suggest, different tariffs are generally applied to different commodities. Governments rarely apply the same tariff to all goods and services imported into the country. One exception to this occurred in 1971 when President Nixon, in a last-ditch effort to save the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, imposed a 10% ad valorem tariff on all imported goods from IMF member countries. But incidents such as this are uncommon. Thus, instead of one tariff rate, countries have a tariff schedule which specifies the tariff collected on every particular good and service. The schedule of tariffs charged in all import commodity categories is called the Harmonized Tariff Schedule of the United States (HTS). The commodity classifications are based on the international Harmonized Commodity Coding and Classification System (or the Harmonized System) established by the World Customs Organization. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 25. Selected US Tariffs - 2004 by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-1a The table below contains a selection of the US tariff rates specified in the 2004 US Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS). The complete US HTS is available at the US International Trade Commision website HERE. The US Treasury department provides historical US tariff schedules dating back to 1997 HERE. To see a small sample of US tariff rates from 1996, Click HERE. The tariff schedule below displays three columns. The first column shows the product classification number. The first two numbers refer to the chapter, the most general product specification. For example, 08 refers to chapter 8, "Edible fruit and nuts; peel of citrus fruit or melons." The product classification becomes more specific for each digit to the right. Thus 0805 refers more specifically to "Citrus fruit, fresh or dried." 0805 40 refers to "Grapefruit," and 0805 40 40 refers to "Grapefruit entering between August 1 and September 30." This classification system is harmonized among about 200 countries up to the first 6 digits and is overseen by the World Customs Organization. The second column gives a brief description of the product. The third column displays the "General Rate of Duty" for that particular product. This is the tariff that the US applies to all countries with Most Favored Nation (MFN) status, or as it is now referred to in the US, "Normal Trade Relations" (NTR). The status was renamed NTR to provide a more accurate description of the term. One provision in our GATT/WTO agreements is that the US promises to provide every WTO member country with MFN status. As a matter of policy, the US also typically grants most non-WTO countries with the same status. For example, Russia is currently (Sept 2004) not a member of the WTO, but the US applies our NTR tariffs rates on imports from them. The final column lists special rates of duty that apply to select countries under special circumstances. For each product you will see a tariff rate followed by a list of symbols in parentheses. The symbols indicate the trade act or free trade agreement that provides special tariff treatment to those countries. A complete list of these is shown below. Symbols that include a "+" or "*" generally refer to special exceptions that apply for some countries with that product. The non-MFN tariff rate is also listed in this column. The only countries now subject to the non-MFN tariffs are Cuba, Laos and North Korea. (Note, Cuba is a WTO member, thus the US does not always honor its WTO obligations) The last countries removed from the Non-MFN category were Serbia and Montenegro in December 2003. Ten years ago, other countries in the non-MFN category included Vietnam, Iran and Afghanistan. Finally, note that some countries, such as Cuba, have other provisions, such as trade embargoes, that further restrict access of their products.
  • 26. Special Tariff Classifications in the US A, A*, A+ Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) (More info: page 11) B Automotive Products Trade Act (More info: page 21) CA, MX North American FTA (NAFTA) Canada and Mexico (More info: page 31) D African Growth and Opportunity Act (More info: page 170) E Carribean Basin Economic Recovery Act (More info: page 23) IL US-Israel FTA (More info: page 26) J, J*, J+ Andean Trade Preference Act (More info: page 29) R US-Carribean Trade Partnership Act (More info: page 171) JO US-Jordan FTA (More info: page 172) SG US-Singapore FTA (More info: page 176) CL US-Chile FTA (More info: page 267) The products presented below were selected to demonstrate several noteworthy features of US trade policy. The WTO reports in the 2004 US Trade Policy Review that most goods enter the US either duty free or with very low tariffs. Coffee and FAX machines are two goods, shown below, representative of the many goods that enter duty free. The average MFN tariff in the US in 2002 was about 5% although for agricultural goods the rate was almost twice as high. About 7% of US tariffs exceed 15%, these mostly on sensitive products such as peanuts, dairy, footwear, textiles and clothing. The trade- weighted average tariff in the US was only about 1.5% in 2003. One interesting feature of the tariff schedule is the degree of specificity of the products in the HTS schedule. Besides product type, categories are divided according to weight, size or the time of year. Note especially the description of ceramic tableware and bicycles. Tariffs vary according to time of entry, as with cauliflower, grapefruit and grapes. This reflects the harvest season for those product in the US. When the tariff is low, that product is out of season in the US. Higher tariffs are in place when US output in the product rises. Notice the tariffs on cauliflower and broccoli. They are lower if the vegetables are unprocessed. If the product is cut or sliced before arriving in the US, the tariff rises to 14%. This reflects a case of tariff escalation. Tariff escalation means charging a higher tariff the greater the degree of processing for a product. This is a common practice among many developed countries and serves to protect domestic processing industries. Developing countries complain that these practices impede their development by preventing them from competing in more advanced industries. Consequently, tariff escalation is a common topic of discussion during trade liberalization talks.
  • 27. Tariffs rates also vary with different components of the same product, as with watches. Note also that watches have both specific tariffs and ad valorem tariffs applied. Notice that tariffs on cars in the US is 2.5%, but the tariff on truck imports is 10 times that rate at 25%. The truck tariff dates back to 1963 and is sometimes referred to as the "chicken tax." It was implemented, primarily to affect Volkswagon, in retaliation for West Germany's high tariff on chicken imports from the US. Today, Canada and Mexico are exempt from the tariff due to NAFTA and Australia will also be exempt with the new US-Australia FTA. The truck tax is set to be a contentious issue in current US-Thailand FTA discussions. The tariff rates themselves are typically set to several significant digits. One has to wonder why the US charges 4.4% on golf clubs rather than an even 4 or 5%. Much worse is the tariff rate on cane sugar with six significant digits. The special tariff rates are often labeled "Free," meaning thise goods enter duty-free from that group of countries. Note that Chile and Singapore sometimes have tariff rates in between the MFN rate and zero. This reflects the phase in process of the free trade area. Most FTAs include a 5-15 year phase in period during which time tariffs are reduced annually towards zero. Selected Tariffs in the US 2004 HTS Code Description MFN/NTR Special Tariff Tariff 0704.10.20 Cauliflower, Broccoli 2.5% (June 5- Free (A,CA, Oct 25) CL,E, IL,J,JO, MX,SG) 0704.10.40 10% (Other, not reduced in Free (A,CA, size) CL,E, IL,J,JO, MX) 0704.10.60 7.5% (SG) 14% (Cut or sliced) Free (A,CA, CL,E, IL,J,JO, MX) 12.2% (SG) Non-MFN: 50%
  • 28. 0805.40.40 Grapefruit 1.9¢/kg (Aug- Free (CA,D,E, Sep) IL, J,JO,MX, SG) 1.6¢/kg (CL) 0805.40.60 1.5¢/kg (Oct) Free (CA,D,E, IL, J,JO,MX, SG) 0805.40.80 2.5¢/kg (Nov- 1.1¢/kg (CL) Jul) Free (CA,D,E, IL, J,JO,MX) 2.2¢/kg (CL, SG) Non-MFN: 3.3¢/kg 0806.10.20 Grapes, fresh $1.13/m3 (Feb Free (A+,CA, 15-Mar 31) CL,D,E, IL,J, 0806.10.40 JO,MX,SG) Free (Apr 1- 0806.10.60 Jun 30) Non-MFN: $8.83/m3 $1.80/m3 (any other time) 6912.00.45 Ceramic tableware; plates not 4.5% Free (A+,CA, over 22.9 cm in maximum CL,D,E, J,JO, diameter and valued over $6 MX,SG) per dozen; plates over 22.9 but not over 27.9 cm in maximum diameter and valued over $8.50 per dozen Non-MFN: 55% 7116.10.25 Cultured Pearls 5.5% Free (A,CA, CL,L,J, JO, MX) 4.1% (SG) Non-MFN: 110%
  • 29. 8703.2x.00 Motor cars, principally 2.5% Free (A+,B, designed for the transport of CA,CL,D, E, persons, of all cylinder IL,J,JO,MX, capacities SG) Non-MFN: 10% 8704.22.50 Motor vehicles for the 25% Free (A+,B, transport of goods (i.e., trucks), CA,CL,D, E, gross vehicle weight exceeding IL,J,MX) 5 metric tons but less than 20 metric tons 15% (JO) 22.5% (SG) Non-MFN: 25% 8712.00.15 Bicycles having both wheels 11% Free (A+,CA, not exceeding 63.5 cm in CL,D,E, IL,J, diameter MX) 2.2% (JO) 9.6% (SG) Non-MFN: 30% 1701.11.05 Cane sugar: 1.4606¢/kg Free (A*,CA, less .020668¢/ CL,E*,IL, J,JO, kg for each MX,SG) degree under 100 degrees Non-MFN: but not less 4.3817¢/kg than .943854¢/ less .0622005¢/ kg kg for each degree under 100 degrees but not less than 2.831562¢/kg
  • 30. 6404.11.20 Sports footwear; tennis shoes, 10.5% Free (CA,CL, basket-ball shoes, gym shoes, D,IL,J+, MX, training shoes and the like: R) Having uppers of which over 50% of the external surface 2.1% (JO) area is leather. 9.1% (SG) Non-MFN: 35% 9506.31.00 Golf clubs 4.4% Free (A,CA, CL,E,IL, J,JO, MX,SG) Non-MFN: 30% 9101.11.40 Wristwatches 51¢ each + 38.2¢ each + 6.25% on case 4.6% on case and strap + and strap + 5.3% on 3.9% on battery battery (CL, SG) Free (CA,D,E, IL,J, J+,JO, MX,R 8517.21.00 Fax machines Free Non-MFN: 35% 0901.21.00 Coffee, non-decaffeinated Free Non-MFN: Free 0902.10.10 Tea, green tea, flavored 6.4% Free (A,CA, CL,E,IL, J,JO, MX) 4.8% (SG) Non-MFN: 20% One thing to think about while reviewing this tariff schedule is the administrative cost of monitoring and taxing imported goods. Not only does the customs service incur costs to
  • 31. properly categorize and measure goods entering the country, but foreign firms themselves must be attuned to the intricacies of the tariff schedule of all of the countries to which it exports. All of this requires the attention and time of employees of the firms and represents a cost of doing business. These administrative costs are rarely included in the evaluation of trade policies. An administratively cheaper alternative would be to charge a fixed ad valorem tariff on all goods that enter, much like a local sales tax. However, it would be almost impossible for political reasons to switch to this much simpler alternative. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 32. Import Quotas by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-2 Import quotas are limitations on the quantity of goods that can be imported into the country during a specified period of time. An import quota is typically set below the free trade level of imports. In this case it is called a binding quota. If a quota is set at or above the free trade level of imports then it is referred to as a non-binding quota. Goods that are illegal within a country effectively have a quota set equal to zero. Thus many countries have a zero quota on narcotics and other illicit drugs. There are two basic types of quotas: absolute quotas and tariff-rate quotas. Absolute quotas limit the quantity of imports to a specified level during a specified period of time. Sometimes these quotas are set globally and thus affect all imports while sometimes they are set only against specified countries. Absolute quotas are generally administered on a first-come first-served basis. For this reason, many quotas are filled shortly after the opening of the quota period. Tariff-rate quotas allow a specified quantity of goods to be imported at a reduced tariff rate during the specified quota period. In the US in 1996, milk, cream, brooms, ethyl alcohol, anchovies, tuna, olives and durum wheat were subject to tariff-rate quotas. Other quotas exist on peanuts, cotton, sugar and syrup. In the US most quotas are administered the US Customs Service. The exceptions include dairy products, administered by the Department of Agriculture, and watches and watch movements, administered by the Departments of the Interior and the Commerce Department. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 33. Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs) by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-3 A voluntary export restraint is a restriction set by a government on the quantity of goods that can be exported out of a country during a specified period of time. Often the word voluntary is placed in quotes because these restraints are typically implemented upon the insistence of the importing nations. Typically VERs arise when the import-competing industries seek protection from a surge of imports from particular exporting countries. VERs are then offered by the exporter to appease the importing country and to avoid the effects of possible trade restraints on the part of the importer. Thus VERs are rarely completely voluntary. Also, VERs are typically implemented on a bilateral basis, that is, on exports from one exporter to one importing country. VERs have been used since the 1930s at least, and have been applied to products ranging from textiles and footwear to steel, machine tools and automobiles. They became a popular form of protection during the 1980s, perhaps in part because they did not violate countries' agreements under the GATT. As a result of the Uruguay round of the GATT, completed in 1994, WTO members agreed not to implement any new VERs and to phase out any existing VERs over a four year period. Exceptions can be granted for one sector in each importing country. Some interesting examples of VERs occured with auto exports from Japan in the early 1980s and with textile exports in the 1950s and 60s. q US-Japan Automobile VERs q Textile VERs International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 34. US-Japan Automobile VERs by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-3a In 1981, the US was suffering the effects of the second OPEC oil price shock. Faced with higher gasoline prices, consumers began to shift their demand from low fuel efficiency US autos to higher fuel efficiency Japanese autos. This increase in auto imports contributed to lower sales and profits of US automakers. Chrysler Corporation nearly went bankrupt in 1981, and probably would have, if the US government had not bailed it out with subsidized loans. The US auto industry filed an escape clause petition with the International Trade Commision, but the ITC failed to find material injury as a result of the Japanese imports. The US was suffering from a recession at that time which also contributed to the decline in demand for US autos. The Japanese, faced with continuing calls by the US auto industry for legislated protection and following discussions with the US trade representative's office, eventually announced VERs on auto exports. These VERs were renewed regularly and lasted until the early 1990s. The bilateral nature of VERs contributes to a series of subsequent effects. Since a VER can raise the price of the product in the importing country, there is an incentive created to circumvent the restriction. In the case of the Japanese auto VERs, the circumvention took a variety of forms. Since the quantity of auto trade between Japan and the US was limited but the value of trade was not, Japanese automakers began upgrading the quality of their exports to raise their profitability. By the late 1980s, new higher-quality auto lines such as Acura, Infiniti, and Lexus made their debut. Alternatively, Japanese autos assembled in the US were not counted as part of the export restriction - only complete autos exported from Japan were restricted. Thus, after the VERs were implemented, Honda, Mazda, Toyota, Mitsubishi, and Nissan all opened assembly plants in the US. A quicker circumvention was accomplished by shipping knockdown sets (unassembled autos) to Taiwan and South Korea, where they were assembled and exported to the US market. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 35. Textile VERs by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-3b Another interesting effect of VERs occurred in the textile industry beginning in the 1950s. In the mid 50s, US cotton textile producers faced increases in Japanese exports of cotton textiles which negatively affected their profitability. The US government subsequently negotiated a VER on cotton textiles with Japan. Afterwards, textiles began to flood the US market from other sources like Taiwan and South Korea. The US government responded by negotiating VERs on cotton textiles with those countries. By the early 1960s, other textile producers in the US, who were producing clothing using the new synthetic fibers like polyester, began to experience the same problem with Japanese exports that cotton producers faced a few years earlier. So VERs were negotiated on exports of synthetic fibers from Japan to the US. During this period European textile producers were facing the same pressures as US producers and the EEC negotiated similar VERs on exports from many southeast Asian nations into the EEC. This process continued until its complexity led to a multilateral negotiation between the exporters and importers of textile products around the world. These negotiations resulted in the Multi-Fiber Agreement (MFA) in the early 1970s. The MFA specified quotas on exports from all major exporting countries to all major importing countries. Essentially it represented a complex arrangement of multilateral VERs. The MFA provided an assured upper limit (ceiling) to the extent of competition that import-competing firms could expect in the US and the EEC. This type of arrangement has sometimes been called an orderly market arrangement. It is also a reasonable example of what has been referred to as managed trade. The MFA was renewed periodically throughout the 70s, 80s and 90s. However, the Uruguay round of the GATT, completed in 1994, renamed the MFA to the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) and specified a ten year transition period during which the ATC will be eliminated. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 36. Export Taxes by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-4 An export tax is a tax collected on exported goods. As with tariffs, export taxes can be set on a specific or an ad valorem basis. In the US, export taxes are unconstitutional since the US constitution contains a clause prohibiting their use. This was imposed due to the concerns of Southern cotton producers who exported much of their product to England and France. However, many other countries employ export taxes. For example, Indonesia applies taxes on palm oil exports; Madagascar applies them on vanilla, coffee, pepper and cloves; Russia uses export taxes on petroleum, while Brazil imposed a 40% export tax on sugar in 1996. In December 1995 the EU imposed a $32 per ton export tax on wheat. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 37. Export Subsidies by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-5 Export subsidies are payments made by the government to encourage the export of specified products. As with taxes, subsidies can be levied on a specific or ad valorem basis. The most common product groups where export subsidies are applied are agricultural and dairy products. Most countries have income support programs for their nation's farmers. These are often motivated by national security or self-sufficiency considerations. Farmers' incomes are maintained by restricting domestic supply, raising domestic demand, or a combination of the two. One common method is the imposition of price floors on specified commodities. When there is excess supply at the floor price, however, the government must stand ready to purchase the excess. These purchases are often stored for future distribution when there is a shortfall of supply at the floor price. Sometimes the amount the government must purchase exceeds the available storage capacity. In this case, the government must either build more storage facilities, at some cost, or devise an alternative method to dispose of the surplus inventory. It is in these situations, or to avoid these situations, that export subsidies are sometimes used. By encouraging exports, the government will reduce the domestic supply and eliminate the need for the government to purchase the excess. One of the main export subsidy programs in the US is called the Export Enhancement Program (EEP). Its stated purpose is to help US farmers compete with farm products from other subsidizing countries, especially the European Union, in targeted countries. The EEP's major objectives are to challenge unfair trade practices, to expand U.S. agricultural exports, and to encourage other countries exporting agricultural commodities to undertake serious negotiations on agricultural trade problems. As a result of Uruguay round commitments, the US has established annual export subsidy quantity ceilings by commodity and maximum budgetary expenditures. Commodities eligible under EEP initiatives are wheat, wheat flour, semolina, rice, frozen poultry, frozen pork, barley, barley malt, table eggs, and vegetable oil. In recent years the US government has made annual outlays of over $1 billion in its agricultural Export Enhancement Program (EEP) and its Dairy Export Incentive Program (DEIP). The EU has spent over $4 billion annually to encourage exports of its agricultural and dairy products. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 38. Voluntary Import Expansions (VIEs) by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-6 A Voluntary Import Expansion (VIE) is an agreement to increase the quantity of imports of a product over a specified period of time. In the late 1980s, VIEs were suggested by the US as a way of expanding US exports into Japanese markets. Under the assumption that Japan maintained barriers to trade that restricted the entry of US exports, Japan was asked to increase its volume of imports on specified products including semiconductors, automobiles, auto parts, medical equipment and flat glass. The intention was that VIEs would force a pattern of trade that more closely replicated the free trade level. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 39. Other Trade Policy Tools by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 10-7 Government Procurement Policies A Government Procurement Policy requires that a specified percentage of purchases by the federal or state governments be made from domestic firms rather than foreign firms. Health and Safety Standards The U.S. generally has more regulations than other countries governing the use of some goods, such as pharmaceuticals. These regulations can have an effect upon trade patterns even though the policies are not designed based on their effects on trade. Red-Tape Barriers Red-tape barriers refers to costly administrative procedures required for the importation of foreign goods. Red-tape barriers can take many forms. France once required that videocassete recorders enter the country through one small port facility in the south of France. Because the port capacity was limited, it effectively restricted the number of VCRs that could enter the country. A red-tape barrier may arise if multiple licences must be obtained from a variety of government sources before importation of a product is allowed. International Trade Theory and Policy Lecture Notes: ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic Last Updated on 5/20/99
  • 40. Trade Questions Jeopardy 10-1 DIRECTIONS: As in the popular TV game show, you are given an answer to a question and you must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is "a tax on imports," then the correct question is "What is a tariff?" 1. An arrangement in which a country agrees to limit the quantity of a good it exports to another country. 2. A payment made by a government to encourage exports. 3. The schedule of tariffs charged in all import commodity categories in the US. 4. A tax levied as a dollar charge per unit of imports. 5. A government policy which favors domestic firms over foreign firms with respect to government purchases. 6. Costly or annoying administrative procedures which make it difficult to import goods into a country. 7. The international organization that maintains the Harmonized Commodity Coding and Classification System for imported goods. 8. A type of quota that allows a specified quantity of a good to be imported at a reduced tariff rate during a specified period. 9. The new name for the multi-fiber agreement. 10. A tax levied as a percentage of the value of an imported good. ©1997-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Last Updated on 6/13/06
  • 41. International Trade Theory & Policy by Steven M. Suranovic, The George Washington University Chapter 20 Trade History and Trade Law ©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, Copyright Terms Table of Contents Problem Sets FROM THE WTO WEBSITE LEVEL 1: Basic Definitional What is the WTO? LEVEL 2: Basic Intermediate 20-0 LEVEL 3: Advanced The WTO in Brief Intermediate Understanding the WTO LEVEL 1 20-1 Measuring Protectionism: Average Jeopardy 20-1 Tariff Rates Around the World Internet Qs 20-1A 20-2 US Trade Policy Highlights Internet Qs 20-1B 20-2a Customs Duties in Government Internet Qs 20-1C Revenue: Britain, France and Internet Qs 20-1D Brazil Problem Set 20 1-1 20-3 US Tariff Policy: Historical Notes Problem Set 20 1-2 20-4 US Trade Law Highlights Answer Keys DOWNLOAD Chapter 20 in PDF format. r Internet Explorer Download Center Answer keys to the problem sets are for sale in Adobe Acrobat PDF format for easier viewing and printing. Purchases must be made using a recent Internet Explorer browser. Revenues from these sales will help us to expand and improve the content at this site.
  • 42. Related Links r WTO Trade Policy Reviews r International Trade Law: An Trade Policy Reviews are conducted Overview periodically by the WTO for every from the Legal Information Institute member country. The secretariat at Cornell University. report provides a comprehensive summary of each country's trade r About the US Trade Representative policies. r The WTO Agreements r About Import Administration at the A description of some of the details US International Trade Admin. behind WTO rules on antidumping measures, subsidies and countervailing measures and r About the US International Trade safeguards. Commission Copyright Notice: The content of this file is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. The content is owned by Steven M. Suranovic. You MAY make a local copy of the work, a printed copy of the work and you MAY redistribute up to 2 copies of the work provided that the work remains intact, with this copyright message attached. You MAY NOT reproduce, sell, resell, publish, distribute, modify, display, repost or use any portion of this Content in any other way or for any other purpose without the written consent of the Study Center. Requests concerning acceptable usage should be directed to the webmaster@internationalecon.com No warranty, expressed or implied, is made regarding the accuracy, adequacy, completeness, legality, reliability or usefulness of the Content at the Study Center. All information is provided on an "as is" basis. HOW TO CITE THIS PAGE Suranovic, Steven, "International Trade Theory and Policy: Trade History and Trade Law," The International Economics Study Center, © 1997-2006, http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ ch20/ch20.html.
  • 43. Measuring Protectionism: Average Tariff Rates Around the World by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 20-1 One method used to measure the degree of protectionism within an economy is the average tariff rate. Since tariffs generally reduce imports of foreign products, the higher the tariff, the greater the protection afforded to the country's import-competing industries. At one time, tariffs were perhaps the most commonly applied trade policy. Many countries used tariffs as a primary source of funds for their government budgets. However, as trade liberalization advanced in the second half of the twentieth century, many other types of non-tariff barriers became more prominent. The table below provides a list of average tariff rates in selected countries around the world. These rates were all taken from the WTO's trade policy review summaries. More details about the trade policies of these countries can be found at the WTO's website at: http://www.wto.org/wto/reviews/tp.htm. Generally speaking, average tariff rates are less than 20% in most countries, although they are often quite a bit higher for agricultural commodities. In the most developed countries, average tariffs are less than 10%, and often less than 5%. On average, less developed countries maintain higher tariff barriers, but, for many countries that have recently joined the WTO, tariffs have recently been reduced substantially to gain entry. Average Tariff Rates Japan (1997) 9.4% European Union (1997) 4.9% Industrial Goods 20.8% Agriculture Norway (1996) 5.6% Canada (1996) 6.6% Overall 1.0% with US Brazil (1996) 12.5%
  • 44. Mexico (1997) 13.2% Overall 4.2% With US Chile (1997) 11.0% El Salvador (1995) 10.1% Cyprus (1996) 16.4% Overall 7.2% with EU 37.6% Agriculture Morocco (1995) 23.5% Benin (1997) 13.0% Zambia (1996) 13.6% Malaysia (1997) 8.1% Thailand (1994) 30.0% Problems Using Average Tariffs as a Measure of Protection The first problem with using average tariffs as a measure of protection in a country is that there are several different ways to calculate an average tariff rate and each method can give a very different impression about the level of protection. Most of the tariffs above are calculated as a simple average. To calculate this rate, one simply adds up all of the tariff rates and divides by the number of import categories. One problem with this method arises if a country has most of its trade in a few categories with zero tariffs, but has high tariffs in many import categories in which it would never find advantageous to import. In this case the average tariff may overstate the degree of protection in the economy. This problem can be avoided, to a certain extent, if one calculates the trade-weighted average tariff. This measure weights each tariff by the share of total imports in that import category. Thus, if a country has most of its imports in a category with very low tariffs, but has many import categories with high tariffs but virtually no imports, then the trade-weighted average tariff would indicate a low level of protection. The standard way of calculating this tariff rate is to divide total tariff revenue by the total value of imports. Since this data is regularly reported by many countries this is a common way to report average tariffs. However, the trade-weighted average tariff is not without flaws. As an example, suppose a country has relatively little trade because it has prohibitive tariffs (i.e. tariffs set so high
  • 45. as to eliminate imports) in many import categories. If it has some trade in a few import categories with relatively low tariffs, then the trade-weighted average tariff would be relatively low. After all, there would be no tariff revenue in the categories with prohibitive tariffs. In this case, a low average tariff could be reported for a highly protectionist country. Note also that, in this case, the simple average tariff would register a higher average tariff and might be a better indicator of the level of protection in the economy. Of course the best way to overstate the degree of protection is to use the average tariff rate on dutiable imports. This alternative measure, which is sometimes reported, only considers categories in which a tariff is actually levied and ignores all categories in which the tariff is set to zero. Since many countries today have many categories of goods with zero tariffs applied, this measure would give a higher estimate of average tariffs than most of the other measures.(1) The second major problem with using average tariff rates to measure the degree of protection is that tariffs are not the only trade policy used by countries. Countries also implement quotas, import licenses, voluntary export restraints, export taxes, export subsidies, government procurement policies, domestic content rules, and much more. In addition, there are a variety of domestic regulations which, for large economies at least, can and do have an impact on trade flows. None of these regulations, restrictions or impediments to trade, affecting both imports and exports, would be captured using any of the average tariff measures. Nevertheless these non-tariff barriers can have a much greater effect upon trade flows than tariffs themselves. The Ideal Measure of Protectionism Ideally, what we would like to measure is the degree to which a government's policies (both domestic and trade policies) affect the flow of goods and services (on both the import and export side) between itself and the rest of the world. Thus, we might imagine an index of protectionism (IP) defined as follows: Where the numerator represents the sum of all exports and imports across all N trade categories given the current set of trade policies, and the denominator represents the sum of all exports and imports that would obtain if the government employed a set of domestic policies that had no impact on trade of goods and services with the rest of the world. If IP = 1, it would indicate that current government policies are completely non- restrictive and the economy could be characterized as being in a pure state of "free trade." If IP = 0, then government policies would be so restrictive as to force the economy into a state of isolation or autarky. If we could calculate and compare the index across many countries, then we could say that countries with a smaller value were more protectionist than countries with a higher
  • 46. value. We could also monitor changes in the index over time for a particular country. Increases in the index value would indicate trade liberalization, while decreases in the index would indicate growing protectionism. The problem with this index, however, is that although it is easy to define, it would be virtually impossible to measure. At least, I know of no way of doing so without making extreme leaps of faith. Nevertheless, the index definition is useful as a way of indicating how far from ideal are any traditional measures of protection such as average tariff rates. Endnotes: 1. It is often claimed that average tariffs in the US were raised to almost 60% by the Smoot-Hawley tariff act of 1930. This figure, although correct, represents the average tariff on dutiable imports only. Thus, the figure somewhat overstates the true degree of protection. In comparison, the trade-weighted average tariff in subsequent years rose only as high as 24.8% in 1932, after which tariff rates fell. ©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Last Updated on 6/14/06
  • 47. US Trade Policy Highlights by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 20-2 Article 1, section 8 of the US Constitution states clearly and succinctly: " the Congress shall have the power ... to regulate commerce with foreign nations ..." This means that decisions about trade policy must be made by the US Senate and House of Representatives, and not by the US President. This clause is rather interesting today because one of the key agencies involved in US trade negotiations is the US Trade Representative's office. This office administers the Section 301 trade cases, has negotiated free trade agreements such as NAFTA, and has negotiated trade liberalization agreements such as the Uruguay round under the GATT. All this from an Executive branch agency which acts as an agent for the President. It would seem, then, that the President does indeed make trade policy. Is this a violation of the constitution? Actually no. The only reason an Executive branch agency, like USTR, can make trade policy is because the US Congress has granted this agency the authority to do so. This issue was in the news recently when the Clinton administration attempted, unsuccessfully (as of Feb 1998), to acquire fast track negotiating authority for new free trade agreements with other countries. Fast track authority would not only give the President and his agents negotiating powers; it would also require the US Congress to vote on any trade agreement presented by the President without amendment. This means that Congress must vote "yea" or "nay" to the entire agreement and cannot make changes to it before the vote. The purpose of fast track authority is to give more credibility to the President and his agents in negotiations with other countries, and hence raise the likelihood that an agreement can be reached. Probably one reason that the framers of the US Constitution reserved trade policy formation for the US Congress was because at the time of US independence and for well over a century after that, tariff revenue was the primary source of funds for the federal government. It must have been thought unwise for the purse strings of the government to be controlled by the President.
  • 48. The adjoining diagram shows US customs duties as a percentage of federal government revenue from 1821 to 1996. Notice that in the early 1800s tariff revenue comprised more than 90% of the federal government budget. This fell during and after the US Civil War in 1860 as alternative sources of funds became necessary to finance the war. Another major decline occurred in the early part of the 1900s shortly after the Constitution was amended to allow the collection of personal income taxes. In the 1990s, more than 70% of federal government revenue came from payroll taxes which consists of both personal income taxes and social security taxes. In contrast, less than 1.5% of revenue came from customs duties. Of course, due to the size of the US federal budget, that still amounts to over $18 billion in tariff revenue. Comparisons with Other Countries Often it is informative to compare one country's experience with others during the same period. Click on the country below to see graphs showing customs duties as a percentage of government revenue in Britain (1821 - 1964), France (1847 - 1988), and Brazil (1937 - 1985). ©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Last Updated on 6/14/06
  • 49. Customs Duties in Government Revenue: Britain, France and Brazil by Steven Suranovic ©1997-2006 Trade 20-2a These graphs depict customs duties as a percentage of federal government revenue in Britain (1821 - 1964), France (1847 - 1988), and Brazil (1937 - 1985). Note that both Britain and France collected a much smaller percentage of government revenue from customs duties in the 1800s compared with the US. In France it was significantly lower and not much different from what prevails in there today. The pattern is Brazil is very similar to the path followed by the US after 1940.
  • 50. ©1998-2006 Steven M. Suranovic, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED Last Updated on 6/14/06